The return of fiscal policy
The new EU macroeconomic activism and lessons for future reform
Abstract
This paper looks at the macroeconomic policy response to the Covid-19 crisis in the European Union (EU) and the prospects for long-term recovery under the Next Generation EU (NGEU) plan. It argues that, unlike what happened following the sovereign debt crisis of 2011-2012, the EU’s strong and prompt response to the pandemic took more into account the lessons from the rethinking of macroeconomic theory which started after the Global Financial Crisis, including as it concerns the use of monetary and fiscal policy as macroeconomic and employment stabilizers, the impact of public investments and industrial policy on long term economic growth, and the role of labour market policies and the welfare state. It concludes reviewing the implications for the current debate on the reform of EU economic governance.
Introduction
The reaction of European Union’s (EU) policy makers to the Covid-19 shock was bold and timely; although they could not avoid a crisis whose dimensions made the 2007-2008 Global Financial Crisis pale by comparison, the governments’ titanic effort managed, with the support of EU institutions, to mitigate the impact on incomes and employment. This came as a welcome change after the calamitous management of the sovereign debt crisis. But it is precisely the extraordinary dimension of the Covid-19 crisis that prompts the question of whether the activism of economic policy denoted a change in the mindset of EU governments and institutions, or simply was the only option available to policymakers to avoid the collapse of their economies. This working paper details the policy answer of EU countries and assesses the perspectives of the long-term recovery plans with an eye to the debate on reform of EU economic governance.
I will point out that the 2008 crisis shook up the Washington Consensus doctrinal framework, making possible an in-depth rethinking of the role of the state in the economy, from the use of monetary and fiscal policy in managing macroeconomic fluctuations to the role of public investments and industrial policy as drivers of long term growth, to even broader themes such as the role of the welfare state, labour market policies and the impact on inequality. A rethinking, however, that in the EU, and most notably in the Eurozone (EMU), was not sufficient to prevent major mistakes in managing the sovereign debt crisis that started in Greece in 2010-2011. The rethinking of macroeconomics had undermined the previous consensus, but a new one did not emerge yet (if ever it will). The Covid crisis came at a time of theoretical uncertainty, with no dominant paradigm; but contrary to the early 2010s, this time the European debate is lively: the voices preaching a return to the pre-crisis status quo are today minoritarian, although certainly not powerless. Whether the changes in the policymakers’ attitude and the discussions of the recent months will eventually evolve into a more functional institutional architecture than the current one is an open question.
This paper will begin by quickly assessing the trajectory of macroeconomic theory in the past decades, showing how today, following the Global Financial Crisis, it is in a state of flux with no clear dominant paradigm. Then, in section 2, I will briefly outline the EU response to the sovereign debt crisis showing that the old consensus recipes were applied and that EU policy makers did not take stock of the debate in macroeconomics unlike what happened for instance in the US. The following sections will show how the Covid pandemics acted as a turning point. Section 3 will describe the bold and timely response to the crisis, while section 4 will be devoted to the Next Generation EU (NGEU) plan for the recovery and for the structural transformation of EU economies. Section 5 will then go through the current debate on EU reform and draw lessons (that go beyond Europe) on how to reconsider macroeconomic and industrial policies after three decades of Washington Consensus dominance. Section 6 concludes.
Rethinking macroeconomics after the 2008 crisis
The institutions that were put in place within the EU with the Maastricht Treaty were not born in vacuum but were strongly influenced by the macroeconomic consensus that emerged from the struggle of ideas of the post WWII period1. The thirty-year period after the end of the Second World War was dominated by the Keynesian theory. Keynes rejected the main result of the pre-1929 neoclassical model, namely that markets could spontaneously achieve full employment equilibrium. The essence of economic policy was, according to the British economist, to intervene in a constant attempt (fine tuning) to compensate, without claiming to replace them, for markets’ inefficiencies and imperfections, to ensure macroeconomic stability and long-term viability.
The State in Keynesian economic theory and policy had a dual role: short-term cyclical regulation, aimed at sustaining economic activity and full employment in periods of slowdown (or cooling it down in case of overheating) by using fiscal and monetary policies; and more structurally, interventions aimed at increasing the "resilience" of the economy - its ability to absorb macroeconomic shocks - and to achieve trajectories of long-term growth in output and jobs at acceptable equilibria from the point of view of economic efficiency. In addition to social justice criteria, the very development and consolidation of welfare systems in the 1940s and 1950s also responded to this need: universal access to health and education, automatic stabilisers such as unemployment benefits, and (last but not least) equitable income distribution, all contributed to increasing the capacity for automatic stabilisation on the one hand, and on the other to increasing what economists clumsily call 'human capital' and therefore the economy's growth potential.
1990s: Macroeconomic policy in the closet
The crisis of Keynesian economics in the 1970s opened a new phase. From the 1980s onwards, the mainstream in economics revolved around the notion of a "natural" equilibrium, to which the economy tends spontaneously in the medium term. Within this “new consensus”, even in the presence of rigidities, persistent deviations from the equilibrium will eventually exert pressure on prices that will bring the economy back to the natural equilibrium. For the theory that dominated macroeconomics in the past decades, therefore, the state has a limited role. As in the old pre-Keynesian model, structural reforms are the main policy tool: curbing monopolies (both in goods production and in labour markets), reducing the weight of the state in the economy, avoiding informational asymmetries, eliminating price and wage rigidities, all this should make it possible to remove the frictions that on the one hand hinder potential growth, and on the other amplify the magnitude of cyclical fluctuations. In this context, discretionary macroeconomic policies are not particularly appropriate; on the contrary, governments should follow clear and predictable policy rules, to reduce uncertainty and allow markets to converge more quickly to their natural equilibrium. It is therefore clear that the new consensus is rather close to the pre-Keynesian neoclassical theory. Macroeconomic policy is only effective in the short run, and only if it remains predictable thus not disturbing the normal functioning of markets whose efficiency is the main pillar of the theory. The persistent deficiencies in aggregate demand that were central to Keynes' analysis are marginal in the mainstream that emerged in the 1990s and dominated the policy landscape until at least the Global Financial Crisis of 20082.
Within the marginal role that the consensus attributes to macroeconomic policy stabilization, monetary policy should be preferred to fiscal policy mostly for two reasons: First, it is less subject to lags in decision and in implementation; second, it can be delegated to independent and technocratic bodies that are not subject to political biases and captured by vested interests. Furthermore, monetary policy aimed at stabilizing inflation will in most cases also keep output and employment at its optimal level (what
The New Consensus shaped the EU institutions that were put in place with the Maastricht Treaty in the early 1990s. The Treaty centered European economic governance on the rejection of active macroeconomic policies. Embracing the “divine coincidence”, the ECB was given a mandate only for price stability, furthermore with considerable autonomy in pursuing it (
The Consensus was not a European peculiarity, but the pressure to reduce the role of the state in the economy was particularly strong in the EU. The perimeter of the welfare state has over time been slowly but pervasively reduced3, the role of automatic stabilisers undermined (somewhat inconsistently with the Stability Pact emphasis on their importance in absorbing business cycle fluctuations), and the cyclical regulation of the economy through macroeconomic policies sacrificed on the altar of 'market flexibility'. The elimination of fiscal policy from the policy makers’ toolbox has over the years particularly affected public investment, an expenditure item politically less sensitive than current expenditure but as crucial for long-term productivity and growth as it is 'invisible' to the public (
Reassessing the role of the State after the Global Financial Crisis
The Global Financial Crisis of 2008 shook the certainties that fed the consensus. The persistence of the recession showed the inconsistency of the claim that markets can quickly return to natural equilibrium following a shock. In 2008 and 2009, in adherence to the old Keynesian theory, monetary policy and then fiscal policy were called to the rescue of an economy that seemed unable to recover on its own. It is true that the Keynesian response was short-lived and that, especially in Europe, there was a rapid return to the fiscal discipline advocated by the new consensus. Nevertheless, economists and policy makers began to question the old recipes and in general the solidity of the foundations of the New Consensus itself. After more than thirty years of emphasis on the supremacy of markets in guaranteeing the optimal allocation of resources and fostering innovation and growth, a wide-ranging debate has begun, and still goes on, on the need to re-assess the role of the government in managing business cycles, in regulating markets and in correcting their inefficiencies. The discussion spares no dogma of the consensus4, from industrial policy to income distribution, from capital controls to trade barriers, from taxation to the role and nature of structural reforms. In particular, the current debate re-assesses the role of fiscal policy, that was previously relegated to a marginal role but in the past decade turned out to be pivotal for macroeconomic stabilisation5, among other things because of the reduced effectiveness of monetary policy; as interest rates progressively converged to zero (
To sum up, after the years of 'market fundamentalism', the profession now seems to have returned, albeit in a confused and non-systematic way, to a broadly Keynesian conception of economic policy: an adaptive process in which, instead of delegating to supposedly efficient markets the task of converging to the best of all possible worlds, policy makers must attempt to guarantee the macroeconomic stability which facilitates investment and accumulation of knowledge and human capital, and thus stable long-term growth. The Covid-19 crisis, that forced governments to bold and improvised response to both the health and the economic emergency, did definitely wipe away the pre-2008 consensus, leaving macroeconomics in a state of flux that is likely going to last some more time.
The Eurozone impervious to change: The sovereign debt crisis
For a long time, the debate on rethinking macroeconomics had little echo in the European policy arena. On the contrary, since 2010 the eurozone crisis has been interpreted as an 'apologue of fiscal sinners', a crisis due to the indiscipline and inefficiency of the governments of some Mediterranean countries (
The Policy Response to the Covid storm
Member States on the frontline
The spring of 2020 has come to reshuffle the cards. The mistakes of previous years seem to have prompted European policymakers to act quickly and well. The first dam against the pandemic wave has been erected by the governments of the member countries, which was inevitable: the EU is a union of sovereign states, that retain exclusive competency on both public health and fiscal policy. For the latter it cannot be otherwise: in accordance with the motto “
Figure 1: Change in government gross debt to GDP, Global Financial Crisis vs Covid. Selected EU Countries
In addition, to cope with the health emergency, states have injected huge resources into the economy to support businesses’ liquidity, to limit the fall in labour income, and to provide guarantees aimed at keeping credit flowing to the productive sector. In almost all European countries, the measures were extended and renewed as the economic effects of the pandemic unfolded; as we write (March 2022), these measures have been mostly withdrawn despite the omicron wave raging as limitations to economic activity have been almost entirely lifted. The effect of these measures on public finances was immediate; debt and deficits exploded (figure 1), and in most EU countries they will continue to rise in 2021. Interestingly, and despite its downsizing mentioned above, the welfare state played an important role. Most of the fiscal support to the economy came from automatic stabilization (figure 2). This is quite different from countries with different institutions, such as the United States, and should be a cautionary tale. Faced with the many stimulus plans (announced but yet to be made into laws) by the Biden administration early in 2021, many claimed that the European Union has been left in the hay once again and has renounced to support its economy. In truth, such a claim does not take into consideration the crucial differences between the two systems. Of course, the figures of the American measures are staggering. However, they include actions that have already been incorporated into European countries’ national welfare systems. US fiscal policy is mainly made up of discretional measures, while the European one leaves a major role to automatic stabilizers.
Figure 2: Cyclical and structural net lending
In most European countries support to labour markets and incomes took the shape of job retention (JR) schemes. For example, thanks to the
The difference between the two crises is striking. The only EU country that resorted to job retention schemes in 2008 had been Germany (and even in that case, to a scale not com6parable with 2020). The relative success of the German labour market after the Global Financial Crisis did push other countries to follow that path in 2020. In fact, this was an explicit recognition that labour markets have specific dynamics that cannot be neglected. The stability of labour relations is crucial for the continuity of investment, including in human capital. While the pre-crisis consensus prescribed flexibility of labour markets, the Global Financial Crisis showed that the capacity to engage in long-term relationships with workers is key, together with stable flows of financing, in guaranteeing adequate accumulation of capital. The German labour market is a very good case in point. Contrary to the conventional wisdom, that sees the Hartz reforms as heavy and far-reaching liberalizations, an important segment of the German labour market, the one linked to manufacturing and business services, is still ruled by long-term agreements between employers, workers, and local work councils
Figure 3: Percent changes in GDP, employment, and incomes in 2020. Selected EU countries
Despite its huge cost, the colossal effort by European governments has borne fruit, and everywhere, at the peak of the crisis in 2020, incomes and employment have fallen significantly less than GDP (
The European support to member states
During the first response phase European institutions acted as guarantors of the member countries’ efforts. In March 2020, the ECB opened a protective umbrella by launching a vast temporary programme of government bond purchases (the
The European Commission also acted quickly to support member countries. First, it activated the suspension clause of the Stability Pact, that will not be reinstated until 2023 (if it ever will; we will discuss the reform of European fiscal rules in section
European institutions also engaged in immediate financial assistance to Member States. In March 2020, the Commission made available €37 billion from the EU budget to finance urgent expenditure (mostly related to health care). In the meantime, with the Council it put together two loans schemes. The first, a €240 billion (2% of EMU GDP) pandemic line within the European Stability Mechanism (ESM) lending for health-related expenditure (from equipment to training of medical personnel to vaccines). The second is a newly created instrument, the €100 billion
Towards the recovery
If Europe's role in the short term could only be limited to support member countries (as was done quite effectively), things change if we look beyond the emergency. As we are slowly putting the crisis behind us, we must tackle the challenges that the pandemic will inevitably leave behind. This means providing the 'global public goods' that are essential for a strong recovery in the long term, such as the transition to sustainable growth, the revival of public investment, digitalisation, and the rethinking of our welfare systems. Not even the largest European countries can hope to meet these challenges alone: the greater effectiveness of coordinated investment, economies of scale, and externalities are all factors that militate in favour of policies conducted, or at least financed and coordinated, at the European level.
This is what inspired the
In addition, resources are allocated to Member States not according to the usual keys, but according to the needs linked to the costs of the pandemic and to the severity of the crisis; this creates some sort of transfer among countries (risk sharing) that had so far been fiercely opposed by Germany and other so-called “frugal” countries (The Netherlands, Austria, Finland). It has been pointed out by many that Italy, usually a net contributor to the budget, will be a net beneficiary of the Recovery and Resilience Facility. Debt will be repaid starting in 2028 (until 2058), hopefully with European resources such as a Carbon border tax. If no progress is made on this side, each country's contribution to the EU budget will have to increase (of quite a modest amount).
Member countries had to prepare Recovery and Resilience programs following strict guidelines both on the destination of funds, such as at least 37% of investment in the green transition and 20% in digitalization, and on the definition of targets and milestone to facilitate ex-post assessment (
Next Generation EU: A radical change but not yet a Hamiltonian Moment
There is little doubt that with Next Generation EU we are in the presence of a radical change: for the first time in its history, the Union is making a joint effort to boost recovery and growth, and the principle of debt mutualisation, albeit temporary, has been accepted. What makes the agreement even more significant is the position of Germany, which had never before agreed to introduce elements of risk sharing into European policies and which, this time, has put its full weight behind the Commission's initiative from the outset (
Germany's historic green light was conditioned by the one-off nature of the NGEU, which does not take over existing debts (contrary to what the US Treasury did with Alexander Hamilton in 1970, for the debts of the American states after the War of Independence). Moreover, except for the plastic tax, there is not agreement among Member States on the other common sources of revenues currently discussed (that would make it possible to avoid an increase in the contributions of the member states to the European budget), such as the taxation of multinationals, the Tobin tax, the carbon border tax. Remember that Hamilton financed the servicing of the newly created federal debt with customs tariffs and an excise duty on whisky and other spirits, the first U.S. federal tax. Finally, the Facility operates by transferring resources for investment programmes that will nevertheless remain national, as the Union does not currently have a spending capacity comparable to that of a federal state (
Lastly, the question of conditionality may become a problem. It was legitimate, indeed necessary, to introduce constraints on the allocation of funds, precisely because of the principle that NGEU is a joint effort aimed at common goals. This conditionality is to be welcomed because it will ensure the overall consistency of national plans and their compatibility with the work program that the Von der Leyen Commission has put in place in late 2019. Nevertheless, the conditions for accessing funding also require abiding by the “country specific recommendations” that the Commission addresses to Member States in the framework of the European Semester. Some fear that these may become, in a near future, a tool to condition access to funding to macroeconomic adjustment programs that would have no justification other than to perpetuate a concept of "permanent austerity" that still has too many partisans in Europe despite the disastrous performance during the sovereign debt crisis.
However, highlighting the grey areas of the Next Generation EU should not lead to neglect its innovative aspect, nor to forget that the EU has been effective in the face of the pandemic, supporting member countries in their emergency effort and launching a common programme to govern recovery in the medium term.
A tool for structural transformation
Only a few studies so far have attempted to assess the short-term macroeconomic impact of Next Generation EU, and they all concur that it will not be extremely large.
In all the studies the value of impact (i.e., short-term) multipliers, while positive, is not really macroeconomically significant. Far from being a surprise, this is consistent with the nature of the programme, whose main objective is to boost potential long-term growth through the financing of investment and reforms. These will be the metrics to assess whether the programme will have been a success.
The Challenges Ahead
The response of EU governments and policy makers to the Covid pandemics was bold and timely. Not only they did shield to the best of their capacities the economies from the pandemics; they also quickly designed a tool for the medium-term transformation of the economy centred on public investment and active government involvement. The question remains, as the two crises in a decade prompted a debate on EU reform, whether this activism is here to stay or whether it was just the product of the exceptional shock that hit the economy in 2020. This debate goes beyond Europe, of course, as the “Maastricht blueprint” has been seen in many countries as the path to growth and stability; an obvious example is of course the CFA franc
Market risk sharing is not and cannot be enough
Following the Global Financial Crisis, the slider between the state and the market has shifted back towards the centre: many economists today have no problem recognising a role in macroeconomic stabilization for monetary and (especially) fiscal policies. In fact, the first twenty years of the single currency and the sovereign debt crisis have shown that markets cannot be relied upon for absorbing macroeconomic shocks and ensure long-term convergence. On the contrary, they sometimes row in the wrong direction. That was evident during the Eurozone crisis, when destabilising capital flows deepened the structural differences among the members of the eurozone, increasing asymmetry of shocks. However, it was also evident during the first decade of the single currency, when excessive capital flows from the core to the periphery of the Eurozone, and misallocation of expenditure in the latter, contributed to large current account imbalances and the build-up of net foreign liabilities. Far from being benign, as some at the time argued (
The coronavirus crisis makes it even more evident that only real mutual insurance mechanisms, typical of a federal budget, could make it possible to guarantee stability and growth by operating alongside (and sometimes in place of) market adjustments. Of course, the federal budget cannot exist without a federal state, and it is obvious that the United States of Europe is today little more than a chimera. Yet, the existence of an ideal solution, however utopian, serves as a benchmark against which to assess the desirability of the many reform proposals that are discussed: any institutional change that acts as a surrogate for a properly federal structure must be encouraged as a means to ensure convergence.
As the consensus in macroeconomics shifts away from the emphasis on markets as the main drivers of both short-run macroeconomic stabilization and investment for long-term growth, the lack of fiscal capacity in the EMU becomes blatant. The European budget and within it structural funds represent a tiny fraction of EU GDP, and they only serve (somewhat successfully in some cases) the objective of catching up of lagging regions. No central capacity for short-term countercyclical stabilization exists in the EU, nor in the Eurozone. At the same time, the EU fiscal rule strongly constrain member states, that need to balance the structural budget and
The absence of a fiscal capacity, be it at the centre or at the Member State level, has over time been compounded by a loss of consistency of the EU framework. The European treaties are consistent with a social contract that gives importance to the insurance role of the government through the welfare state; a system in other words, where automatic stabilization plays an important role. In the US, on the contrary the social contract gives a low weight to the insurance role of the government. Coherently with this democratic choice, discretionary macroeconomic policies in the US are active to smooth income fluctuations. In other words, two equally legitimate and consistent systems can be designed: one in which a marginal role for the welfare state is compensated by active discretionary fiscal and monetary policies (the US); or a European treaty-consistent one in which constraints to discretionary policy go hand in hand with a role for automatic stabilization.
A well-functioning common currency needs to resolve the inconsistency and endow itself with appropriate tools for implementing fiscal policies. The remainder of this section will explore some possible avenues to that end.
A central fiscal capacity
Looking at the experience of the United States, the most effective way to endow the eurozone with the capacity to implement fiscal policy is to create a fiscal capacity at the central level. Next Generation EU could be a first step towards such a European fiscal capacity. Hopefully European countries will be able to use the Recovery Facility to revive the economy, channel the resources efficiently into a green and digital transition that can no longer be postponed and transform the Union into a dynamic knowledge-based economy. The success of the NGEU package could pave the way for a discussion on the next step, the creation of a permanent fiscal capacity. It would not be the first time that temporary instruments have acted as icebreakers and led to innovations in European governance. The Recovery Facility possesses (albeit at an embryonic stage) the characteristics of a federal-type ministry of finance: its own borrowing capacity, a (prospective) ability to finance itself from its own resources, an allocation of resources that combines the needs of individual countries with the pursuit of common goals such as the ecological transition and digitalisation. Speculative attacks on sovereign debt, and the risk of free riding by national governments, so feared by the “frugals”, would be greatly reduced if the eurozone were to equip itself with such an instrument.
While it would be a first best in terms of efficacy (for example in dampening asymmetric shocks), a central fiscal capacity would be quite difficult to put in place, even abstracting from the scepticism of some Member States worried by the possibility of free riding and moral hazard. The creation of a European capacity to tax and spend would require finding a solution to several interconnected problems: how to ensure the accountability in front of voters (once again,
While waiting for the political conditions for a permanent Recovery fund to be reunited, a possible surrogate of a federal budget could be represented by a European unemployment benefit scheme, which has been discussed since the 1990s at least (among the many proposals, see e.g.,
Public finances’ sustainability and investment: Reforming fiscal rules
The discussion on the creation of a fiscal central capacity, or at least of a joint stabilization mechanism, rages among academics and policy-makers; nevertheless, it is still quite far from becoming a priority in the European political agenda. On the contrary, the next few months will see a heated debate on the reform of the Stability and Growth Pact. It would be simplistic to say that European fiscal rules forced the season of austerity after 2010. This was the result of a vision that traced financial instability and the debt crisis back to the profligacy of southern Eurozone countries, whereby, with or without the existing fiscal rules, European countries would have walked that path anyway. Still, the institutions for European macroeconomic governance were consistent with that turn to austerity and, as demonstrated by the management of the Greek crisis, provided the appropriate instruments to pressure even the most recalcitrant governments.
The activation of the suspension clauses of the Stability Pact in March 2020 was motivated by the pandemic that was just starting; however, the Commission had already, just a few weeks earlier, opened a consultation process on the reform of the rules; an assessment which was based on a surprisingly severe assessment of the existing framework10. The Commission finally took on board the criticisms that had been unanimously voiced by independent economists for several years: (a) the current framework was overly complex, arbitrary, and difficult to enforce; (b) the rules allowed to control deficits, but much less debt, which was the true threat to public finances’ sustainability; (c) public investment, which is generally easier to reduce than current spending, had been penalised at least since the Global Financial Crisis; (d) finally, the Commission acknowledged for the first time that the current framework was pushing many governments to implement procyclical fiscal policies, reducing spending when the economy was slowing down (particularly between 2010 and 2013). In short, between the lines the Commission acknowledged that European rules had made fiscal policy a factor of instability rather than stabilisation.
The consultation process was suspended by the Covid emergency, but in the early Summer 2021 Commissioner Gentiloni relaunched it, while announcing that the Stability Pact suspension clause would remain activated at least until all of 2022. It is highly likely that the existing rules will be replaced before they come back into force, especially in light of the geopolitical developments of the Spring 2022. The Commission is expected to table a proposal in the fall of 2022.
The reform process comes at a moment in which public investment is at the centre of the stage. The gap in public capital is evident in European countries as well as in other advanced economies and is compounded by the future needs related to the ecological and digital transition. A big push in public investment was the most notable feature of the recent coalition agreement in Germany: The Green Party managed to obtain an acceleration of the exit from fossil fuels, brought forward to 2030 (from 2038) when 80% of the electricity supply will have to be ensured by renewable energy. This will require colossal public investment (estimated at least 450 billion euros over the next ten years, see
Considering the revival of public investment in the academic and in the policy agenda, it is not surprising that most reform proposals (for a few examples, see
The golden rule is not a new idea, and in the past it has been criticized (see e.g.
Dervis and Saraceno argue that the implementation of a golden rule of this kind would serve the purpose of focusing on the nature and quality of public spending in relation to the growth objective. It would also force European policymakers to have a periodic and transparent discussion on the investment needs of their economies, and to coordinate policies as part of a process that would increase participation, cohesion and legitimacy in the Eurozone.
Whatever reform proposal will eventually gather the consensus of EU governments, it is essential to protect national public investment from the injunctions of European fiscal rules if European countries are to support the public investments needed to boost their economies and face the challenges of climate change and digitalization. It is likely that the Commission will converge towards a reform proposal that excludes at least part of investment expenditure from the deficit calculation, including expenditure related to the ecological transition and the Green Deal (the Commission's proposal could resemble the proposal made by
Managing public debt: From solvency to sustainability
The response to the pandemic has led to a massive increase of public debt across advanced and emerging economies (
In past sovereign debt crises, the debate was dominated by the idea that governments need to ensure the sustainability of public finances by keeping revenues in line with expenditures and by repaying past debt, as any good household would do, in order not to mortgage the future of its children. This narrative was the economic (when not moral) support of austerity policies. Nevertheless, historically very few governments have repaid their debt. The good household narrative is flawed because it neglects the perpetual nature of the government that can indefinitely refinance its debt as long as it is capable to service it (i.e., pay the interest). Said differently, a government, contrary to a household who eventually will come to the last period of its life and repay its debt, does not need to be solvent (
Therefore, what matters for governments is sustainability, i.e., the capacity to service the stock of debt, that crucially depends on the interest rate it pays and on its capacity to generate resources (the growth rate of the economy). A notable feature of advanced economies in the past decades, has precisely been that interest rates have been generally lower than growth rates, thus avoiding explosive debt paths even in the presence of persistent government deficits (
Since the beginning of the nineties, nominal interest rates have fallen significantly in almost all industrial countries; more importantly, they have fallen to a greater extent than inflation. The result is a fall in real interest rates that has helped alleviate the debt burden. The apparent rate, the ratio of interest expenditure to public debt, has fallen despite a major increase in debt; this has shown in a drop of the interest payment to GDP ratio, and it happened not only in virtuous countries but also in those where public finances are most fragile (Figure 4).
Figure 4: Debt and interest payments as % of GDP
Recent literature has leaned on this long-term trend on the one hand to try to understand its reasons, on the other to try to evaluate its persistence. In a standard theoretical framework, the natural interest rate leads to the equilibrium of savings and investments at the level corresponding to full employment; its downward trend therefore indicates, in general terms, a context of excess of the former over the latter. This rate is estimated by many economists to be zero or lower for the majority of advanced economies, which since 2009 at least have been in a situation of zero lower bound (
Inflation, and central bank interest rates: Much ado about nothing?
Starting from the spring 2021, with the post-pandemic recovery, inflation in both the US and the eurozone increased well beyond the 2% central banks’ target. These, however, did not rush into a policy reversal. The Fed is preparing for a gradual tightening in 2022, and the ECB has no plans to raise rates until 202312. This caution is mainly explained by the belief that the spike in inflation is temporary and specific to some sectors. As the economy rebounded after the pandemics, in early 2021, on one side confidence returned; and on the other a part of the large mass of savings accumulated in 2020 (partly forced and partly precautionary) has poured into the markets in the form of demand for consumption or investment by firms. The fiscal stimulus plans, especially in the United States, compounded this increase in private demand. Nevertheless, supply has struggled to follow demand. First, during the pandemics there were bankruptcies and destruction of productive capacity, although minimized by public aid. Then, even for companies and sectors in which the activity has continued, the pandemic has disarticulated the production process. Supply chains have deteriorated with the crisis and need to be rebuilt when not outright reinvented; this created sectoral bottlenecks that slow down the recovery and contribute to the temporary surge in inflation (
In short, we are still far from the smooth functioning of the markets before the pandemic, which should not be surprising given the nature and violence of the shock that has hit the world economy. However, there is no reason to believe that the distortions and bottlenecks we are witnessing will lead to a permanent increase in inflation. First, because the institutions that favoured the de-anchoring of expectations and the price-wage spirals of the past are not in place anymore (no European country has today a mechanism to index wage increases to inflation). If anything, besides temporary wage hikes in some countries or sectors, we still see wages that barely keep up with productivity growth. Second, while it is almost certain that the organization of production processes and the sectoral distribution of activity that will emerge at the end of this adjustment phase be somewhat different from those we are used to,. nothing tells us that there will be persistent inflationary pressures in this new world. On the contrary, all the forces that have compressed inflation in recent years are bound to weigh as much if not more than before: macroeconomic and geopolitical uncertainty, an ageing population, growing inequality and wage compression, precariousness in labour markets, the growing burden of debt (public and private), the slowdown in technical progress and innovation. All this has pushed in the past, and will push in the future, to an increase in savings rates and to stagnant investment. The current low interest rate environment is likely to continue.
Solving the trade-off between fiscal discipline and risk sharing
The overall favourable conditions for debt financing and sustainability do not mean that there are no longer any constraints on the increase in debt in individual countries. Even if the general environment is likely to remain one of low rates and cheap money for the next decade, EU countries may find themselves sanctioned by markets, either because of unsound management of public finances or because of speculation and financial markets turmoil. This is why it is important that rules effectively reconciling fiscal discipline with renewed fiscal space (as discussed above) are complemented by tools aimed at protecting Member Countries by unwarranted market pressure. The crucial trade-off for a monetary union is between fiscal discipline and the efficiency with which they manage to
A federal treasury would be an obvious, as well as today politically unrealistic, solution to the trade-off. In its absence, however, it is possible to think of a "synthetic treasury", issuing Eurobonds to then finance member states while maintaining a differentiated treatment according to the credit risk of each of them.
By issuing a common bond that would be a (badly needed) European safe asset, the EDA could act as a key factor in reducing systemic uncertainty, thus stabilising market expectations on overall debt sustainability. In the meantime, it would align the cost of debt with the ‘fundamentals’ of each Member State, so it could allow the adoption of rules giving to states more leeway, without sacrificing neither fiscal discipline at the national level nor the financial stability of the Union.
While the idea of an EDA may seem at first sight quite unorthodox, it has several characteristics that may make it politically viable. The first and more important is the absence of mutualization, that would de facto eliminate incentives to free ride or moral hazard13. The second is that substituting the ECB in financing the Member States it would facilitate the normalization of monetary policy, that could go back to its core business. Then, the bonds issued by the EDA would constitute a safe asset and help the Euro acquire a role in line with the economic power of its economy. Last, but not least, the EDA could be designed to support and efficiently manage public debt with any type of fiscal governance, be it (as discussed above) a central fiscal capacity or a renewed role for national fiscal policies. In a complex (political and institutional) setting like the European one, this seems an important point in favour of the proposal.
A broader role for the ECB
The process of rebalancing the respective role of markets and government in managing the economy cannot leave out a rethinking of monetary policy. The review of the monetary policy strategy announced in July 2021 (
As we have seen, The ECB statute dates to the period when the consensus in macroeconomics postulated that a central bank should only address inflationary risks and that these were related to the quantity of money in circulation. Within this framework, growth and convergence (e.g., between euro area economies) were the prerogative of supposedly efficient markets that from the public sector would only require an appropriate environment: stable prices to avoid surprises, public finances under control, structural reforms to limit distortions that hindered the efficiency of markets. These beliefs underpin the European institutional architecture based on a limited interaction between monetary and fiscal policies, an independent central bank, and a constant emphasis on controlling inflation in the tradition of the German Bundesbank. This is why for most of the twenty years of existence of the single currency, economic policy has had an asymmetrical behaviour and a fundamentally deflationary impact on the economy: always ready to tighten at the slightest sign of overheating and much less reactive in case of a slowdown.
The 2008 crisis challenged the consensus, and it became evident that stagnant prices and deflation are as pernicious to growth as excessive inflation, but much harder to fight. If, to cope with excessive price increases, the central bank can always increase rates and curb aggregate demand, to combat the tendency to stagnation and deflation it is constrained by the zero lower bound. This is why in recent years all central banks have had to resort to unconventional policies such as massive purchases of securities or the provision of long-term liquidity to the banking sector); and that is why central banks have invoked (sometimes, as in Europe, implored; see the already mentioned Draghi Jackson Hole speech, in 2014) the help of fiscal policies.
All the major central banks have in the recent past reassessed their strategies noting that, as we saw above, deflationary risks in the coming years will persist. Recently the US Fed adopted an average inflation rate target that requires it to pursue an inflation target above 2% after a period in which it has been consistently lower. The ECB has not been so radical14: it dropped the old target of inflation below, but close to, the (impassable) ceiling of 2%, to adopt a symmetrical targeting whereby inflation can remain above (but close to) 2% following periods of stagnant growth and prices. While it is true that an average inflation target would have been a more marked departure from the old strategy, the adoption of a symmetrical objective should contribute in the future to reducing the structurally deflationary stance of monetary policy. The ECB's change of direction is further reinforced by the abandonment of the monetary aggregates’ growth target. This is a technical point, which is also made irrelevant by the fact that in the past the objective has often been disregarded without too much stress. However, the symbolic significance of dropping it is important, since the focus on monetary growth targets is a legacy of a monetarist period in which prices and the quantity of money were believed to be strongly correlated, giving the central bank alone the task of controlling inflation. Today, the ECB joins other central banks in recognizing that the link between the quantity of money in circulation and inflation is tenuous and that to bring inflation to the targeted levels requires cooperation between monetary and fiscal policies.
The latest sign of the formalized "politicization" of European monetary policy is the abandonment of the so-called market neutrality, which required not to use valuations other than the effect on inflation in deciding the types of securities to purchase. From now on, the ECB will contribute to a European green industrial policy by embedding the threats to financial and price stability into its policy analysis and by favouring purchases of “green” bonds aimed at financing investments in the ecological transition. Again, it is not the first nor the most daring of central banks to have embarked on a green strategy (see
The ECB strategic review simply formalizes a change in the bank’s objectives and instruments that has
Conclusion
The Covid-19 crisis turned around the economic policy debate in Europe. Guiltily clinging to the old consensus, during and after the sovereign debt crisis, European policymakers had opened up as little as possible to the debate raging among economists on the role of economic policy as an engine of macroeconomic stabilization and long-term growth as well as on the best institutional set-up for the single currency. The pandemic swept away those hesitations. In the Spring of 2020, in a matter of a few weeks the EU introduced instruments for common crisis management and for boosting the recovery that could, if successful, lead to a reorganisation of European public policies (especially macroeconomic policies) quite different from the one that showed so many shortcomings during the sovereign debt crisis. Interdependence and the need for risk-sharing mechanisms are now becoming obvious, even in Brussels and Berlin, in fields such as health, public investment, the ecological and digital transition and the management of asymmetric macroeconomic shocks.
The debate on rethinking macroeconomics is far from settled, but a consensus is emerging on the fact that fiscal policy is back in town. Today, as we discussed above, EU institutions do not provide room for it, thus being clearly at odds with the
The last, but not least important, message of this essay is that the return of fiscal policy needs to be framed within in a major overhaul of EU institutions. Better and more credible fiscal rules, the joint management of debt through a Debt Agency capable of minimizing borrowing costs while keeping government accountable and a less technocratic ECB would be parts of a consistent and renewed system of macroeconomic governance capable of providing space for policy action while avoiding instability and opportunistic behaviour.
References
Acknowledgements
This paper was prepared following the Seminar on Employment-first Strategy and Sustainable Economic Recovery from COVID-19 crisis, which was co-organized by the Chinese Ministry of Human Resources and Social Security (MOHRSS) and the International Labour Organization (ILO), and took place in Beijng on 15 October 2021. The author is thankful to the participants of the workshop for the useful discussion, particularly to Iyanatul Islam and Aurelio Parisotto who provided insightful comments. The usual caveats apply.