< Main ILO website

International Labour Organization Logo, working paper International Labour Organization Logo, working paper
Table of Contents

The regulation of collective dismissals:

Abstract

Introduction

Economic and social rationale of collective dismissal procedures

Addressing negative externalities of collective dismissals

Internalizing costs of collective dismissals

Improving risk-sharing and redistributing the losses

Reducing information asymmetries

Decreasing transaction costs

Reducing uncertainties

Collective dismissals: Overview of provisions contained in the ILS

Which ILS are relevant for collective dismissals?

Definition of collective dismissals for economic reasons: substantive and quantitative aspects

Special procedures triggered in case of collective dismissals: information and consultation of workers’ representatives

Special procedures triggered in case of collective dismissals: notification to competent authorities

Special measures to avert or minimize dismissals for economic reasons and to mitigate their effects

Collective dismissals: Overview of national laws and practice

Sources of information on national laws and practice

Definition of collective dismissals for economic reasons: substantive and quantitative aspects

Special procedures triggered in case of collective dismissals: Information and consultation of workers’ representatives

Special procedures triggered in case of collective dismissals: Notification to competent authorities

Special measures to avert or minimize dismissals for economic reasons and to mitigate their effects

Final assessment

Annex

References

Acknowledgements

Copyright


See all ILO working papers

.

(no footnote loaded)

The regulation of collective dismissals:

Economic rationale and legal practice

Abstract

This paper offers a legal and an economic analysis of collective dismissals procedures. First, it explains the economic rationale for having collective dismissal procedures in place, in light of the fact that labour markets are not perfect. Second, it overviews the international labour standards pertaining to collective dismissals for economic reasons. Third, using information for 132 countries, it reviews and compares legal practices of collective dismissals throughout the world in the light of the international labour standards. The paper shows that the statutory regulations of collective dismissals are in fact very different from regulations of individual dismissals, not only in the types of the legal procedures that they contain, but also in their economic objectives. The paper also discusses the caveats of making cross-country comparisons of the degree of worker protection, and of the costs to employers, provided by these regulations.

Introduction

Regulation of collective dismissals for economic reasons1 is one of the key pillars of employment protection legislation (EPL). Despite being a key labour market institution, EPL remains controversial, as manifested in both academic debates (for reviews, see Skedinger, 2010; Betcherman, 2012; 2014) and policy debates (for examples, see World Bank, 2013; IMF, 2016; OECD, 2007 and subsequent publications; ILO, 2015a). Interestingly, most of the debate has focused on only one EPL pillar – protection in case of individual dismissals.2 The collective dismissals pillar has received much less attention.

The objective of this paper is to contribute to fill this void. First, it reviews and compares legal practices of collective dismissals throughout the world in the light of international labour standards (ILS). Second, it discusses not only their legal aspects, but also the economic and social rationale. It shows that the statutory regulations of collective dismissals are in fact very different from regulations of individual dismissals, not only in the types of the legal procedures that they contain, but also in their economic objectives. Most importantly, the paper shows why collective dismissals is one of the areas that can particularly benefit from being regulated.

As is the case with provisions on individual employment termination at the initiative of the employer, provisions on collective dismissals usually reflect the de facto asymmetry of contractual rights of either party to terminate employment relationship, as well as the need to address the consequences of this asymmetry and to redress the unequal bargaining power between workers and employers (Buechtemann, 1992; Deakin, 2014).3 While termination of the contract by the worker – exercising the fundamental right to protect his or her freedom of work – is oftentimes merely an inconvenience for the employer, the termination of the employment relation by the employer can result in insecurity and poverty for the workers and their families, particularly during the periods of high unemployment (GS 1995; ILO, 2015a). The consequences of collective dismissals go beyond individual employers and workers and affect the economic health of communities. For this reason, they are particularly prone to market failures.

Market failure is a situation in which the individual incentives for rational behaviour do not lead to rational outcomes for the society. For example, it may be rational, optimal, and normal for a specific company to dismiss a group of workers. However, such choice may not necessarily be fully optimal for the society. Market failures may result from a variety of factors, such as negative externalities (the fact that collective dismissals may impact not only these workers, but also other workers of the area or sector, and their families), information asymmetries (enterprises and workers do not have the same knowledge about the economic situation of the enterprises), transaction costs (it may be too costly to have several individual dismissals as compared to a collective dismissal), and uncertainties. Thus, the specific rules governing collective dismissals (whenever they exist in national laws or practice) first and foremost aim at correcting such market failures, by incorporating social considerations into the individual decision-making. The challenge for a legislator, however, is not to impose regulations that unduly restrict collective dismissals, as this may also lead to the hesitation by enterprises to invest and create new jobs. Rather, it is to restore the socially-desirable optimum and improve labour market efficiency.

The rules governing collective dismissals contain many elements similar to the regulation of individual dismissals, including notably the necessity to provide a valid reason for dismissals. However, one of their main differences lies in a special procedure that needs to be followed to accomplish several terminations of employment. Such special procedural requirements may include but not be limited to: consultations of the employer with workers’ representatives, notifications to the competent authorities, undertaking measures to avert or minimize terminations and to mitigate their effects, establishing criteria for selection for termination and priority of rehiring. While they cannot always prevent job losses, these procedures aim at guaranteeing an orderly process, and striking the right balance between the needs of workers, employers, and societies at large4.

A novelty of this paper is to show how various factors that lead to market failures are addressed in the international and national laws and legal practice. As such, the paper highlights that assessments of the regulations of collective dismissals can particularly benefit from economic thinking, outside of neoclassical economics, including economics of information asymmetry, contract theory, and institutional economics. The paper shows that the alternative to collective dismissals is not the absence thereof, but several individual dismissals, which, without a specific procedure designed to address them, risk posing challenges not only to workers, but also to businesses and to societies, both in terms of administering them and in terms of dealing with their consequences. By doing so, the paper complements and extends (both in argumentation and in the number of countries covered) comparative overviews of collective dismissals’ provisions in legal scholarship (such as Collins, 2012; Countouris et al., 2016).

While this paper focuses on describing the logic, and comparing the regulations of collective dismissals across different countries, it is important to remember that, for any proper analysis of the impact of these regulations on economic outcomes (such as employment, unemployment, productivity, to name a few), such regulations should be placed in a wider context of economic, employment, vocational education and training, as well as social security policies (notably unemployment insurance, social assistance, early retirement). These contexts can have a significant influence on the concrete shape of collective dismissals provisions, as they may often complement or substitute them. Considering all such policies goes beyond the subject of the present study, and yet the absence of such comparison limits the scope of the identification of differences and commonalities across countries. Another limitation of the study is that it does not systematically analyze internal enterprise practices meant to prevent as much as possible the need for collective dismissals (e. g. working time savings accounts) or to mitigate the effects for dismissed workers (life-long-learning). It does, however, provide examples of such practices, for those countries for which such information is available. More generally, studying preventive approaches of employment protection that, while trying to limit interference with the functioning of companies/markets as much as possible, seek to avoid the need for collective dismissal or, where it cannot be avoided, to reduce the negative consequences of collective redundancies, is a very promising area for further research.

The paper is structured as follows. Section 1 provides economic and social rationale for various regulations and discusses what impact such provisions, as well as their absence, may have on various outcomes of workers, employers, and societies. Section 2 reviews ILS relevant to collective dismissals. Section 3 examines examples of national law and practices in comparison with the ILS. The last section concludes with thoughts on how to assess whether regulations actually do achieve their market-failure-correcting objectives.

Economic and social rationale of collective dismissal procedures

Economic theory, including the work of Nobel-prize winners Ronald Coase and George Akerlof, widely recognizes that labour markets are not perfectly competitive (for overviews, see Kaufman, 2007, or Lee and McCann, 2011). As Robert Solow has argued, the labour market is better understood as a “social institution” and thus the concept of perfect competition should not be applied to the labour markets at all (Solow, 1992). When basic assumptions of the neoclassical economic model are relaxed, such as by introducing transaction costs (Coase, 1937; 1960) and information asymmetries (Akerlof, 1970), there is an economic case for labour market regulations (Kaufman, 2007; Boeri and van Ours, 2008).

It is thus widely recognized that EPL in general exists because it helps to remedy market failures, created by transaction costs and externalities, but also by incomplete contracts that do not ensure workers fully against income losses (Pissarides, 2001; Bertola, 2009). EPL in general aims at improving the efficiency of the labour markets (Nickell and Layard, 1999; Boeri and van Ours, 2008). It can also provide more equitable outcomes, being an effective alternative to redistribution systems (ibid). Many countries adopted, and continue adopting, EPL as part of their development, recognizing that a balanced employment protection is likely to be compatible with longer-term development goals (Deakin, 2014; Deakin et al., 2014).

The sheer size of these negative externalities, transaction costs, and information asymmetries is substantially larger in case of collective dismissals than in case of individual dismissals. Given this, special collective dismissal procedures exist in many countries in addition to rules governing individual dismissals. They have at least six specific explicit goals to substantially reinforce the efficiency and equity objectives of the general EPL regime.

Addressing negative externalities of collective dismissals

First and foremost, special procedures for collective dismissals reflect the need to address important negative social and economic consequences that collective dismissals may have. Those are related to the fact that in collective dismissals, the social value of even one individual’s job can go beyond its private value (Cahuc and Zylberberg, 2006), and the value of worker’s human capital can be greater for a society than for an individual firm (Booth and Zoega, 2003). Depending on company’s size and the number of workers to be dismissed, collective dismissals affect not only individual workers, but also whole sectors of activity, labor market segments, and geographical areas. A relatively large collective dismissal may depress the local economy and, thereby, increase the likelihood of dismissals in other local firms. There may also be risks of poverty and social exclusion not only of the affected workers, but also of their families, and severe consequences for the health of the affected population, including stress over job loss, sleep deprivation, depressions, and even suicides (for a review, see Countouris et al., 2016). In addition, many workers entering suddenly into unemployment will interact in their job search activities, creating congestion, with negative effects on search efforts of new unemployed workers and decreasing their likelihood of finding a suitable job at a local level. Thus, the laws and practices of many jurisdictions regarding collective dismissals aim at avoiding systemic disruption of the labour market and of the local economy.

Internalizing costs of collective dismissals

The social costs of collective dismissals may include, but are not limited to, providing the economic support to the unemployed; expenses linked to retraining workers and helping them in finding employment; expenses linked to relocations of workers and their families; economic desertification of an area and consequences for other enterprises and sectors, including education and medical sectors, among others; as well as various hidden costs including health care and criminal justice (Collins et al., 2012). Thus, as a second objective, both ILS and the national laws and practices of many jurisdictions on collective dismissals explicitly aim at internalizing these costs, in other words, involving the employers in sharing the burden of costs with the society, with public authorities and public budgets. Moreover, research shows that cooperation between tripartite social partners with a view to anticipating and preparing restructuring processes can help to avoid or lessen the overall costs (Eurofound, 2011).

Improving risk-sharing and redistributing the losses

Since having all of the social costs borne by the employer may be not be possible, nor desirable, the third objective of the collective dismissals procedure is to redistribute the losses and share them equitably – not only between workers and societies, but also between employers and societies. For this reason, both ILS and national laws and practices also often explicitly aim at finding solutions to prevent such costs, jointly by the tripartite social partners. Social dialogue is key in this respect, as it can result in ingenious solutions to preserve jobs and improve outcomes for the workers, the employers, and the communities at large. Involvement of public authorities at the consultation, notification, and/or approval stages, if well designed, can help develop solutions to mitigate and better forecast the consequences of collective dismissals.

Reducing information asymmetries

The effective realisation of these objectives can only be possible if full information is available to all parties. Thus, the fourth objective of the procedure is to reduce information asymmetries between workers, employers, and also public authorities. This asymmetry is due to the fact that employers have more and better information on the economic situation of a firm that leads them to consider collective dismissals.

The information asymmetry is principally reduced at the notification and consultation stages of the collective dismissals procedures. Unless addressed, information asymmetry may create an imbalance of powers, aggravating market failures. The costs of such consequences are usually not incorporated (and cannot be incorporated) in individual private contracts between employers and employees. Rather, they are shifted to the taxpayers or to social security systems (Skedinger, 2010), hence again begging for involvement of the tripartite social partners in their avoidance. Moreover, the respect of the information and consultation procedures may also have other effects, such as reducing a “moral hazard” situation where, once the dismissal plan is agreed, but there was no information provided, or provided too late, the employer may have an incentive to conduct a dismissal differently from the one agreed upon.

Decreasing transaction costs

In the absence of a collective dismissals procedure, carrying out multiple individual dismissals may be quite costly for an employer. Thus, the fifth objective is to create a special avenue aiming at decreasing transaction costs of multiple dismissals. In most of the legal traditions, collective dismissals procedures are designed to respond to objective circumstances faced by an enterprise, and to accommodate the business needs by streamlining several individual dismissals into a constructive channel. The special procedure reflects the recognition of the necessity to provide the employers with an efficient way to terminate the employment of workers by preserving their businesses and competitiveness, taking into account the requirements of the enterprise (GS 1995, p.106). It offers a possibility for employers to find solutions jointly with workers and their representatives over the number of separations, the type of separations (some workers may accept voluntary departures), the schedule, and the list of workers concerned. As the procedure often includes the possibility of selecting and rehiring employees, employers may be in a position to strengthen their productive capacities.

Public authorities may also play a positive arbiter role in facilitating and streamlining terminations for economic reasons, especially where social partners cannot find an agreement. They often have special competence and experience to handle sensitive dismissal issues and to plan many of their aspects.

Many good practices aim at rendering collective dismissals sensible and fair. When several individual terminations need to be effectuated, collective dismissals procedure aims at offering a transparent and fair alternative, which can help mitigate the adverse psychological climate in which redundancies take place, and thus help preserving company’s productivity and reputation. Effective management of collective redundancies may also help maintain trust and provide a decent basis for restructuring the business, helping employers to preserve their uniqueness rather than re-starting their business from ground zero.

Reducing uncertainties

Last but not least, because both individual and collective dismissals may be challenged in courts by workers and unions, the expectation of a certain court’s decision will directly impact the likelihood and the content of individual worker’s actions against their own dismissal. Collective dismissals procedure conducted in an open manner and involving genuine negotiations can reduce litigation risks and their uncertain legal outcomes, which is of value for both workers and employers (Oyer and Schaefer, 2002). For example, some authors show that the passage of the Civil Rights Act of 1991 in the US has affected the methods of displacement used by American firms (Oyer and Schaefer, 2000). To the extent that it was legally possible, some firms preferred to implement a collective dismissal procedure instead of many successive individual dismissals, in order to avoid high costs of wrongful termination litigation. If many workers were to be dismissed at the same time through a special procedure, it would be very difficult to prove discrimination in courts thereafter (ibid; Malo and Pérez, 2003). Thus, one of the outcomes of the special collective dismissals procedure is often a legitimization of the whole dismissal program.

In light of the above, any assessments of the impacts of collective dismissals procedures need to take into account their positive and negative effects on workers, on employers, and on the societies. They should also strive to see what the counterfactual would have been. In other words, any assessment needs to address the extent to which terminating several workers through a collective dismissal procedure is indeed more efficient and optimal for enterprises and for the societies than several terminations through an individual dismissal procedure.

Collective dismissals: Overview of provisions contained in the ILS

Which ILS are relevant for collective dismissals?

The Termination of Employment Convention, 1982 (No. 158) and the Termination of Employment Recommendation, 1982 (No. 166), thereafter C158 and R166, are the main ILO technical standards addressing the termination at the initiative of the employer. They provide important guidance on the regulation of both individual and collective dismissals.

C158 and R166 stipulate that national governments may, in consultation with employers’ and workers’ organizations, put in place special procedural requirements for terminations of employment for economic, technological, structural or similar reasons, whether they concern one, or several workers. The explicit objective of such procedures is “to avert or minimize as far as possible termination of employment for reasons of an economic, technological, structural or similar nature, without prejudice to the efficient operation of the undertaking, establishment or service, and to mitigate the adverse effects of any termination of employment for these reasons on the worker or workers concerned” (R166, Para 19).

As per March 2020, C158 has been ratified by 35 out of 187 ILO member States.5 The moderate level of ratification of this instrument may be explained by different factors. One of them is that the Convention currently has a “no conclusions” status6 and is not promoted for ratification on a priority basis (ILO, 2009a). Another is the persistent debate on the role of EPL, which is often reduced to seeing EPL as purely a cost to the employer, without recognizing its beneficial aspects (for a review of both advantages and downsides of EPL, see Skedinger, 2010). Nevertheless, the level of ratification of C158 is comparable to other technical ILO conventions.7

Such special procedural requirements may include, but are not limited to: consultations of workers’ representatives, notifications to the competent authorities, undertaking measures to avert or minimize termination and to mitigate their effects, establishing criteria for selection for termination and priority of rehiring. The ILS explicitly recognize the importance of involving the tripartite parties in the deployment of these measures.

The ILO Committee of Experts on the Application of Conventions and Recommendations (CEACR), in its general observation on C158 in 2008, noted that, regardless of whether the Convention 158 is ratified or not, the basic principles of these standards are actually embedded in the legislations of a wider set of countries, including “notice, a pre-termination opportunity to respond, a valid reason and an appeal to an independent body” (ILO, 2009a).

Although they do not refer directly to collective dismissals for economic reasons, several other ILS outline important employment protection principles for some categories of workers. These instruments include both fundamental conventions and several technical conventions and recommendations (Box 1).

The ILS are the key benchmarks against which national laws can be meaningfully compared, regardless of whether they have been ratified or not. The current paper does not intend to measure the national laws’ ratification and implementation of ILS, but rather identify to what extent national legislations contain provisions outlined in these standards (especially the two specific technical standards governing employment termination: C158 and R166). This is different from comparing regulations against a benchmark of “no provisions”, or “minimum” provisions in a given sub-sample of countries, as may be done elsewhere. Using ILS as a benchmark for cross-country comparisons is legitimate, since ILS are one of the key sources of national labour laws.

Box 1. Other ILS relevant to the regulation of termination of employment

In parts addressing specifically terminations on economic grounds, both individual and collective, C158, Art. 13(3) and R166, Para. 20(3) make explicit reference to Workers’ Representatives Convention, 1971 (No. 135). This instrument stipulates that workers’ representatives in enterprises have to enjoy effective protection against any act prejudicial to them, including dismissal, based on their status or activities as a workers' representative or on trade union membership or participation in trade union activities, in so far as they act in conformity with existing laws or collective agreements. The Workers’ Representatives Recommendation, 1971 (No. 143) also details specific measures that should be taken to ensure effective protection of workers’ representatives.

In addition, two fundamental ILO conventions are of relevance to collective dismissals. One is The Right to Organize and Collective Bargaining Convention, 1949 (No. 98), according to which trade union membership, participation in union activities outside working hours or, with the consent of the employer, within working hours (C098, Art. 1) constitute prohibited grounds of dismissal (anti-union discrimination). Another is The Discrimination (Employment and Occupation) Convention, 1958 (No. 111). It defines the term “discrimination” as including any distinction, exclusion or preference made on the basis of race, colour, sex, religion, political opinion, national extraction or social origin, which has the effect of nullifying or impairing equality of opportunity or treatment in employment or occupation. Those constitute prohibited grounds for dismissal (discrimination: Art. 1, 1(a) of Convention No. 111). Convention No. 111 also includes additional principles in Art.5. It also stipulates that all persons should, without discrimination, enjoy equality of opportunity and treatment, in particular in respect of security of tenure of employment. With regards to collective dismissals, that these non-discrimination principles be also respected when determining criteria for selection of employees to be dismissed and priorities for rehiring.

Among technical conventions, The ILO’s Maternity Protection Convention, 2000 (No. 183), in its Article 8, declares unlawful for an employer to terminate the employment of a woman during her pregnancy or maternity leave or during a period following her return to work to be prescribed by national laws or regulations, except on grounds unrelated to the pregnancy or birth of the child and its consequences or nursing. Under the ILO’s Workers with Family Responsibilities Convention, 1981 (No. 156), family responsibilities may not, as such, constitute a valid reason for termination of employment. In addition, the marital status and family situation should not as such, constitute valid reasons for termination of employment. Measures and national regulations in respect of pregnancy, maternity, and family responsibilities are all considered to be essential for promoting gender equality in employment, and hence to eliminating sex discrimination, which constitutes prohibited ground for dismissal under fundamental Convention No. 1118. The HIV and AIDS Recommendation, 2010 (No. 200), states that real or perceived HIV status should not be a cause for termination of employment (Para. 11). Lastly, the Violence and Harassment Recommendation, 2019 (No. 206) suggests that appropriate measures to mitigate the impacts of domestic violence in the world of work could include temporary protection against dismissal for victims of domestic violence, as appropriate, except on grounds unrelated to domestic violence and its consequences (Para 18c).

Definition of collective dismissals for economic reasons: substantive and quantitative aspects

Strictly speaking, C158 and R166 do not refer to the term “collective dismissals” as such. Rather, both contain a special part (Part III in both) entitled “Supplementary provisions concerning terminations of employment for economic, technological, structural or similar reasons”. Article 13 (2) of C158 provides that “National laws or regulations may limit the applicability [… of these provisions] to cases in which the number of workers whose termination of employment is contemplated is at least a specified number or percentage of the workforce”. Thus, C158 leaves it to the national regulators to determine whether such procedures are to be applied in the case of any individual termination for economic, technological, structural or similar reasons, or whether the national law and practice may provide for a quantitative limit - a quantitative definition of collective dismissal, which, when met, would trigger these special procedures. In other words, C158 recognizes the operational requirements of the enterprise as a valid reason for dismissals, and dismissals for such reasons may be individual or collective.

Importantly, according to the General Survey of the ILO CEACR (GS 1995), the fact that the special procedures for terminations of employment for economic, technological, structural or similar reasons are contained in “Supplementary provisions” part of the Convention does not mean that they are secondary. The word “supplementary” is used in the meaning “additional”; “additional” to other provisions of the Convention (GS 1995).

Special procedures triggered in case of collective dismissals: information and consultation of workers’ representatives

ILS stipulate that when the employers contemplate collective dismissals, they should foresee providing the workers' representatives with the information and conducting a consultation (C158, Art. 13 (1); R166, Para. 20 (1,2)). Information and consultation are two distinct processes, and one should precede the other. The ILS also provide guidance as to their purpose, the content, and the timing. The term “workers' representatives” signifies “the workers' representatives recognized as such by national law or practice, in conformity with the Workers' Representatives Convention, 1971 (No. 135)” [C158, Art. 13 (3)].

The purpose of providing all the relevant information is to “to enable the workers' representatives concerned to participate effectively in consultations” [R166, Para. 20 (2)], while the purpose of the consultation is to “avert or to minimize the terminations and measures to mitigate the adverse effects of any terminations on the workers concerned” [C158, Art. 13 (1b)].

The content of the information should be “relevant” [C158, Art. 13 (1a)], and include, at the minimum, “the reasons for the terminations contemplated, the number and categories of workers likely to be affected and the period over which the terminations are intended to be carried out” (ibid). R166 also provides that it is the “relevant information on the major changes contemplated and the effects they are likely to have” (Para. 20 (2)) to be supplied. Relevant and complete information gives the parties the opportunity to discuss the basis on which particular employees will be made redundant, to consider whether the overall number of employees being made redundant can be reduced, and what can be the measures for such reduction. Indeed, consultation without information leaves little room for negotiation and may signify that the employer has made decisions unilaterally. When a proposal for dismissal is presented as final, it will not give employees’ representatives an opportunity to constructively participate in discussions on the possible way forward. Consultation without information would thus miss the objectives of C158 to seek genuine effective solutions through constructive social dialogue and to mitigate their adverse effects. Consultation should be viewed as an opportunity “for an exchange of views and an establishment of a dialogue which can only be beneficial for both the workers and the employer.” (GS 1995, p. 105). Consultations can also be seen as a key safeguard to ensure that dismissals are not taking place on prohibited grounds and there are no disguised discriminatory dismissals.

As clarified by the General Survey of 1995, “finding alternative employment” is the only explicitly prescribed measure of the content of the consultation in C158, while the rest of the consultations’ content is left to the national methods of implementation. It is implicit, however, that consultations should also be based on the supplied information.

ILS also stress the importance of the timing of consultations. The information is to be provided “in good time” [C158, Art. 13 (1a), R.166, Para. 20(2)], and the opportunity for consultation is to be given “as early as possible” [C158, Art. 13 (1b); R166, Para. 20(1)]. The more time the workers are given to better understand the business reasons behind the proposals to dismiss employees, the better they can prepare for consultation and ensure that they can effectively participate in them. Moreover, the information and consultation take place even at the stage when “employer contemplates the introduction of major changes in production, programme, organization, structure or technology that are likely to entail termination” [R166, Para. 20(1)], in other words, even before the stage at which actual terminations become inevitable. Involving workers’ representatives into the major changes in the organization that may result in employment termination is likely to produce more satisfactory solutions (GS 1995, p. 107). Good timing, clear and comprehensive information, and transparent and genuine consultations with workers’ representatives are the procedures designed to channel grievances, to provide necessary space for social dialogue, and to create win-win situations for workers, employers, and societies.

Special procedures triggered in case of collective dismissals: notification to competent authorities

According to ILS, employers contemplating terminations for economic, technological, structural, or similar reasons, should notify competent authorities of such intentions. ILS provide guidance as to the timing, the content, and the form of notification to public authorities [C158, Art. 14 (1) and 14(3)] although leaving the modalities thereof to national law and practice. The international instruments do not, however, specify, whether terminations also have to be authorized by competent authorities, nor do they prescribe the exact role that public authorities should play upon the receipt of the notification.

The key objective of the notification is to give public authorities a possibility to play a mediator role between employers and workers in finding agreement and appropriate solutions, and mitigate its effects both for the affected workers and for the wider community. Thus, notification is a first step towards ensuring that public authorities can effectively play such roles during and after collective redundancies. The role of public authorities often goes well beyond simply taking note of terminations’ notification. It involves, among others, carefully elaborating social measures, securing funds for alternatives to dismissals (such as work-sharing) and for mass claims of unemployment benefits, preparing job placement centers. Indeed, R166, Para. 19 (2), states that “where appropriate, the competent authority should assist the parties in seeking solutions to the problems raised by the terminations contemplated”. Training and retraining options should be considered by public authorities with the collaboration of the employer and the workers' representatives concerned [R166, Para. 25 (1)].

Special measures to avert or minimize dismissals for economic reasons and to mitigate their effects

ILS explicitly provide that the procedures contained therein serve the objective of averting or minimizing termination of employment and mitigating its effects [C158, Art. 13 (1b); R166, Para. 19(1)]. R166 also puts forward a set of specific measures to reach this objective, including the obligation of the employer to consider other measures before termination of the employment; criteria to be applied in selecting workers whose employment is to be terminated; and priority rules for rehiring dismissed workers.

The ILO CEACR in its General Survey of 1995 reminds that “it is important to ensure that certain protected workers, such as workers’ representatives, are not dismissed in an arbitrary manner on the pretext of a collective termination of employment” (Para. 335). In this context, the special regimes of protection for several categories of workers (e.g. trade union members, workers’ representatives, women on maternity leave) are not to be neglected.

Obligation of the employer to consider other measures before termination of the employment

R166, Para. 21, contains a non-exhaustive set of measures which should be considered with a view to averting or minimizing terminations of employment. It provides that such measures “might include, inter alia, restriction of hiring, spreading the workforce reduction over a certain period of time to permit natural reduction of the workforce, internal transfers, training and retraining, voluntary early retirement with appropriate income protection, restriction of overtime and reduction of normal hours of work.” Furthermore, Para. 21 provides that “where it is considered that a temporary reduction of normal hours of work would be likely to avert or minimize terminations of employment due to temporary economic difficulties, consideration should be given to partial compensation for loss of wages for the normal hours not worked, financed by methods appropriate under national law and practice”.

Criteria for selection of employees to be dismissed

R166, Para. 23 (1), provides that there be specific criteria for selection of workers whose employment is to be terminated for reasons of an economic, technological, structural or similar nature. These criteria should be “established wherever possible in advance, which give due weight both to the interests of the undertaking, establishment or service and to the interests of the workers”. The determination of these criteria, of their order of priority and of their relative weight is left to national practice.

Priority of rehiring

R166, Para. 24 (1), provides that “[w]orkers whose employment has been terminated for reasons of an economic, technological, structural or similar nature, should be given a certain priority of rehiring if the employer again hires workers with comparable qualifications, subject to their having, within a given period from the time of their leaving, expressed a desire to be rehired”. R166, Para. 24 (2), also states that such priority of rehiring may be limited to a specified period of time.

Collective dismissals: Overview of national laws and practice

Sources of information on national laws and practice

The examples of national law and practice provided in this section are drawn from the ILO EPLex database9, as well as from other ILO publications, and publications of the ILO staff. Where appropriate, some arguments of this paper are also supplemented by examples found in the literature.

Our objective in this paper is to make a comparative analysis of legal regulations in as many countries as possible in order to advance convincingly our legal and economic arguments. However, such cross-country legal information is not easily available, and when it is, it may be available for different time periods in different countries. In order to reach the largest comparison base, we chose the year 2010. This is the year for which we have the largest number of country-specific observations from two sources combined: the ILO EPLex database - the official ILO database dedicated to the topic of employment termination - and Muller (2011), an ILO publication. Unless stated otherwise, exact details of laws are contained in these sources. In total, our comparative analysis is based on the information for 132 countries with available data. All maps and tables in this paper are based on this sample.

We are aware that some readers may find this information outdated. However, first, what matters for us in this paper is not the exact wording of the laws today, but the diversity of experiences and examples that can be found on the international level. The key point of this paper is precisely to analyze how counties compare (and differ) in the variety of legal tools that they use to regulate the same phenomenon, to show the ingeniousness of the legislators, and to show that sometimes the same objectives may be reached by different tools. Second, in fact, much of the legal information presented here is still of relevance today. This is because collective dismissals is a legal area where reforms are not frequent. Indeed, at the revision stage of this paper, we verified the ILO EPLex database. At the moment of writing, 57 countries contained information updated till the year 2018 or 2019. Out of them, only 6 experienced reforms of collective dismissals since 2010, or 10,5 per cent. Appendix 1 lists all countries with this latest available information, and records which countries experienced reforms. The details of the reforms are also provided in Box 2. Summing up, as this paper is the first attempt to analyze a cross country data on collective dismissals, the comparison base of the year 2010 is still useful for exploratory purposes, with much of the information still being meaningful.

Box 2. Examples of recent reforms of collective dismissals procedures

Two countries experienced major reforms of EPL in the context of the global economic crisis that started in 2008. In Spain, the reform of 2012 (Royal Decree-Law 3/2012) focused, among other issues, on collective dismissals, and in particular on the abolition of the administrative approval in the procedure for adopting collective dismissals. Also, the valid reasons for redundancies were clarified, to include current or foreseen losses, as well as a persistent decrease (at least three consecutive quarters) in ordinary revenue or sales, even when a company receives profits (Valverde, 2017; ETUI, 2016a; ILO EPLex).

In Portugal, the government, on the recommendation of international financial institutions (the “Troika”), changed labour laws several times in 2011-14. The area of collective dismissals was one of those affected by these changes (Vilarinho Marques & Mendes Ferreira Roberto, 2017; ETUI, 2016b; ILO EPLex). The Law 23/2012 concerned changes to seniority rules previously applicable to determining the order in which workers were terminated; changes to the justification of dismissals; and elimination of the obligation to transfer the employee to another suitable position. However, the Constitutional Court considered some of these rules to be unconstitutional (Decision 602/2013), which led to a reversal of the reform (Law 27/2014).

Both countries - Portugal and Spain – have ratified Convention No. 158. The reforms in response to the economic crisis were commented by the CEACR, as these cases reflect the interference of several factors affecting tripartite social dialogue on labour market reforms and the intervention of public and judicial authorities in the implementation of labour laws.

Similarly, in the Netherlands, several important labour market reforms occurred in 2013-2015. In 2013, a tripartite Social Pact was concluded on rebalancing flexibility and security, and this was followed by the adoption of “Work and Security Act” in 2014. Since the entry into force of the law in 2015, the preventive system remains, but the employer cannot choose freely between the cantonal judge and the public administration body [UWV). Dismissals for economic reasons must be decided by the UWV, in addition to some changes related to severance pay (Boot and Erkens, 2017; ETUI, 2016c; Dekker, Bekker and Cremers, 2017).

Examples of other reforms of collective dismissals over the 2010-2018 period include Romania in 2011 (Uluitu, 2017), the United Kingdom in 2013 (Neal, 2017), and Greece in 2011 (ILO EPLex).

This section presents a variety of legal practices of regulating collective dismissals. It also shows that there are several countries in which specific provisions on collective dismissals do not exist in statutory laws. Interestingly enough, while C158 allows each member State to determine the specific requirements necessary to apply its provisions, so as to respect different industrial relations traditions and specific features of national labour markets, in the developed countries there is more similarity than divergence across countries with respect to collective dismissals procedures (similar findings are also reported in Countouris et al., 2016; OECD, 2013). In the European Union countries, in a large part this is due to the European Council Directive 98/59/EC of 20 July 1998 on the approximation of the laws of the member States relating to collective redundancies, which has been transposed into national legislation of 27 countries (Box 3). The key differences across countries are embedded in the implementation practices, the definitions and content of the provisions, the roles of various competent bodies and of courts, different historical powers of tripartite actors, compliance and enforcement (ibid).

Box 3. Regional regulation as a source of national labour laws

The European Council Directive 98/59/EC of 20 July 1998 on the approximation of the laws of the member States relating to collective redundancies, which has been transposed into national legislation of 27 countries, contains requirements similar to the ones outlined in C158 and R166. It provides that any employer considering collective redundancies must hold with the workers’ representatives consultations in good time with a view to reaching an agreement. It provides that consultations must at least cover the ways and means of avoiding collective redundancies or reducing the number of workers affected and mitigating the consequences through accompanying social measures aimed notably at aid for redeploying or retraining those workers made redundant. The quantitative definition of collective redundancies has also been provided in the Directive.

Definition of collective dismissals for economic reasons: substantive and quantitative aspects

Definitions of collective dismissals vary tremendously across countries. In the 132 countries with available information, 22 countries have formal laws that contain neither the definitions of collective dismissals, nor any additional specific procedures for terminations of workers on the grounds of economic, technological, structural or similar reasons, beyond procedures previewed for any individual dismissal. In 50 countries, there is no definitional distinction between collective and individual dismissals on economic grounds (the statutory law does not contain any numerical threshold or time limit); however, specific procedural rules are provided. In other words, such special provisions are applied for terminations for economic, technological, structural or similar reasons regardless of the number of employees involved. In the largest group of 60 countries, laws provide for specific thresholds limiting the applicability of the Parts III of C158 and R166. Stated differently, they contain both substance and quantity components of the definitions for collective dismissals (Figure 1).

The substance component of the definition implies that collective dismissals are dismissals based on economic, technological, structural, or similar reasons. Normally, they cannot be based on worker-related reasons, such as worker’s capacity or conduct, but only on the operational requirements of the undertaking, establishment or service. Only the operational requirements of the enterprise are recognized as a valid reason for collective termination of employment.

Examples of scenarios in which collective dismissals may take place include employer’s insolvency or cessation of activity, cessation of a job, scaling down of an enterprise, or an enterprise’s transformation. Depending on a jurisdiction, each of these scenarios may trigger a different employment termination procedure. This is especially the case of insolvency or the cessation of the enterprise activity, which may be governed not only by labour law, but also by civil law and specific bankruptcy provisions.

Figure 1. Legal definition of collective dismissals for economic reasons triggering specific procedures

Source: ILO EPLex and Muller (2011). Information as of 2010. See also Annex 1.

The ILO CEACR stresses the importance of the manner in which the termination of an employment relationship is defined. If the termination of the employment relationship at the initiative of the employer “is wrongly labelled by him [or her] for example as resignation, breach of contract, retirement, modification of the contract, force majeure or judicial termination, the rules of protection governing termination might apparently seem not to apply; but the use of such terminology should not enable the employer to circumvent the obligations with regard to the protection prescribed in the event of dismissal.” (GS 1995). While this quote applies generally to the dismissal at the initiative of the employer, the same can be said about the choice over collective versus individual dismissal procedure.

Given this, it is important to ensure, both through laws that include the right incentives, but also through enforcement policy measures, that employers do not deliberately stagger or scatter redundancies, when this is done exclusively with the aim of avoiding specific procedures such as notification and/or consultations10. For this reason, voluntary redundancies (employees volunteering to be considered for redundancy) are usually included in the total number in order to determine whether a collective dismissals procedure is to be followed11. Depending on a jurisdiction, when a separate redundancy situation within the same organization is taking place, additional dismissals may or may not be taken into account when considering new proposal to make employees redundant. While there is not much guidance on the supranational level on how to deal with issues of deliberate mislabeling of dismissals or their scattering, some legal systems have robust jurisprudence allowing to prevent or to revert the process. In some instances, such as in Italy before the recent labour reforms of the mid-2010s, it was not uncommon to reinstate workers terminated individually and to request that employers follow a collective dismissals procedure.

The way the collective dismissals unfold may also depend on who decides that it is to take place, for example, if it is a decision taken unilaterally by management, or did it involve a works council. When the decision is at the employer’s discretion, judges may be more likely to evaluate the validity of economic grounds for dismissals. Whether the presented economic grounds are indeed valid or not may depend on the extent to which reductions in profits or sales were expected or anticipated, whether the reductions are current or past. Some of the recent reforms dealt precisely with such elements of substantive definition of collective dismissals. Examples include the 2012 labour law reform in Spain, where the definition of dismissals on economic grounds was broadened and the concept of “negative economic situation” was clarified.

The quantitative component includes a definition of how many workers are terminated in order for such series of dismissals to be considered as collective rather than individual. While C158 provides that there may be a difference in procedural requirements depending on the number of workers terminated on economic and similar reasons, it leaves it to national jurisdictions to provide (or not) any quantitative definitions or thresholds to collective dismissals.

When quantitative definitions exist, they most frequently relate either to a specific number of employees involved (often with thresholds depending on the enterprise size), or the percentage of the enterprises workforce, dismissed over a specified period of time. Some specialists also highlight a sometimes present local element of the collective dismissals’ definition, which may refer to a specific area concerned (Heinsius, 2009). Even more than a geographical area, an important element is the definition of a unit, establishment, or enterprise, within which a specific number of workers may be terminated on economic grounds. If terminations can be spread easily across different units or areas, it may be easier to avoid collective dismissals procedures. It is thus important that both legal and enforcement frameworks provide clear definitions of such units and areas, and contain measures to prevent circumventing them. In some countries (ex.: Austria12), quantitative definitions take into account workers’ age, providing for a lower threshold for older workers. Table 1 highlights examples of quantitative definitions found throughout the world.

Table 1. Examples of quantitative definitions

Country

Time period concerned

Number of workers concerned

EU countries that (literally) transposed the European Union Directive 98/59/CE of 1998

Over a period of 30 days

  • At least 10 in establishments normally employing more than 20 and less than 100 workers

  • At least 10% of the number of workers in establishments normally employing at least 100 but less than 300 workers

At least 30 in establishments normally employing 300 workers or more

Or, over a period of 90 days

At least 20, whatever the number of workers normally employed in the establishments in question

Angola

Over a period of 3 months

5 or more workers

Argentina

No time period specified

More than 15% of workers in undertakings employing less than 400 workers

More than 10% of workers in undertakings employing between 400 and 1000 workers

More than 5% of workers in undertakings employing more than 1000 workers

Armenia

Over a period of 2 months

At least 10 workers or more than 10% of the workforce

Australia

No time period specified

15 or more employees

Canada

Within a period not exceeding 4 weeks

At least 50 employees in an industrial establishment

China

No time period specified

More than 20 employees, or less than 20 but accounting for at least 10% of the total number of employees

France

Over a 30-day period

Different provisions regarding whether less than 10 or more than 10 employees are concerned

Japan

Over a period of 1 month

30 employees or more

Morocco

No time period specified

All or part of the workers in undertakings with 10 or more workers

Peru

No time period specified

More than 10% of workers

South Africa

No time period specified

For employers with more than 50 employees who contemplate to dismiss at least:
- 10 employees out of up to 200 employees;
- 20 employees out of 201 to 300 employees;
- 30 employees out of 301 to 400 employees;
- 40 employees out of 401 to 500;
- 50 employees out of more than 500 employees

United States

Over a period of 30 days

Mass lay-off: loss of employment not resulting from a plant closing affecting:
- at least 500 or more employees or,
- 50-499 employees where that number is at least 33 % of the employer's workforce.
Plant closure: a shut-down of one or more facilities or operating units that results in a loss of employment for 50 or more employees

Zimbabwe

Over a period of 6 months

Five or more employees

Source: ILO EPLex and Muller (2011). Information as of 2010. Note that, as shown in Appendix 1, the information was the same for Argentina, Armenia, Australia, China, Morocco, and South Africa in 2019; and for Japan and Zimbabwe in 2018, the latest year of available data.

From the economic point of view, provisions such as those defining quantitative definitions of collective dismissals are often setting a more objective scene for the procedures to unfold, and decrease uncertainty about the nature that the dismissals will have. They also serve a safeguarding role for disguised collective dismissals. Thresholds also matter if the dismissal process involves negotiations over the number of employees to be dismissed and over the alternatives to dismissals to be sought.13

Special procedures triggered in case of collective dismissals: Information and consultation of workers’ representatives

Providing information to (notifying) workers’ representatives is legally mandated in 97 countries out of 132 countries with available information (Figure 2). In other words, out of 110 countries that have any specific procedures related to dismissals on economic grounds, whether with or without quantitative definition of dismissals, almost 85 per cent contain this legal requirement. Consultation is legally mandated in 87 countries (Figure 3). The ten countries in which notification to workers’ representatives, but not the consultation, is a legal requirement are Armenia, Azerbaijan, Bangladesh, Comoros, Kazakhstan, Montenegro, Nigeria, Sudan, Uganda, and the United States of America.14 However, even if a legal requirement to notify and consult is absent, information and consultation may exist in practice and be regulated by collective agreements.

A particularly high value is accorded by the law to sharing information and carrying out consultation in a transparent way as a means of “moderating or reducing the social tensions inherent in any termination of employment for economic reasons” (GS 1995).

Figure 2. Information to workers’ representatives: legal requirement

Source: ILO EPLex and Muller (2011). Information as of 2010. See also Annex 1.

The content of the information varies tremendously across jurisdictions. In some, the law may set detailed lists of the items to be provided, such as the criteria to select workers to be made redundant. In others, the type of information to be provided is also subject of collective agreements.

The economic and social rationale for legally defining the content of the information is to help mitigate significant psychological risks of workers, even those who will not be dismissed. The extent of information’s completeness may also be an important means to keep workers motivated and engaged during the dismissal process, and protect their well-being (ACAS, 2014). Employee motivation, in turn, is essential to maintaining a sound social climate propitious to the continuation of the employer’s activities that are both productive and prone to innovations (Acharya et al., 2013). Given this, for employers, the alternative to not providing information is not an “easier” dismissal procedure, but possibly an adverse social climate, disloyalty, strikes, lower productivity of remaining workers, sizeable production disruptions and potentially hurt image and reputation loss for the company. Similarly, the absence of social measures proposed by the enterprise may also affect its reputation, hurting its business, while a well-designed social measure may be used as a public relations strategy.

Figure 3. Prior consultations with workers’ representatives: legal requirement

Source: ILO EPLex and Muller (2011). Information as of 2010. See also Annex 1.

In practice, however, providing full information may be challenging. Some information may be commercially sensitive, and hence not readily available for disclosure. It is thus important for the employers to strike the right balance as to which information to provide. In this respect, the laws often serve as providing only the minimum guidance, while the information actually provided in practice may be substantially richer.

The content and objectives of consultations, as well as their nature, differ both within and across countries, but usually presuppose an active role of the workers’ representatives. They may also depend on the exact reason for terminations (whether it is a plant closure, a reorganization, or an abolition of a job). In some countries, especially in the European Union member States, the objective of consultation of employers with workers’ representatives is to reach an agreement. However, reaching such agreement or consensus may not always be required.

In some countries, laws and practices make a distinction between consultations and negotiations. When negotiations are common in national practice, they may pre-determine the type of information that is to be provided. In other words, the objective and the content of the information may differ depending on whether it serves mere informative purpose, or also consultation, or negotiation. The content of negotiations may include, but not be limited to, the number of workers to release, priority rules, schedule of release (for example, redundancies may be taking place by teams of workers with similar functions), additional compensations, but also retraining options and placement in other units of the enterprise. Negotiations of each of these items are often interconnected and may be traded against each other. They may also include additional items, beyond what is prescribed by laws and collective agreements, and determined by the ingeniousness of social partners seeking mutually beneficial solutions. In some countries (for example, France), it is standard practice for workers to obtain financing from the employer to hire an external expert to verify some of the business information on the basis of which dismissal justification is made, and help finding an alternative reorganization solution. Effective negotiations can also provide an incentive for both employers and workers to reach an agreement without having to recur to the mediation of the third parties.

In some jurisdictions, the laws may prescribe that the consultations not only aim at averting or minimizing terminations, but also that they mitigate the adverse effects of terminations. The legislation of several countries contains legally binding requirements for employers to come up with accompanying social measures (Box 4). Such measures may have different names, but are frequently referred to as “social plans” or “programs of settlement of the manpower problems” (see, for example, Cosio et al., 2017).

Box 4. Social plans

Social plan is a set of social measures that accompanies collective dismissals. Examples of such measures include job placement assistance, additional payments for early retirements, individualized “severance packages” (which may be over the legal requirements), and provision of vocational training grants to workers (for other examples, see ACAS, 2014; NERA, 2016).

In many jurisdictions, elaboration of a social plan is a legal obligation for an employer contemplating collective dismissals. Examples include, among others, Algeria, Cambodia, Gabon, or Morocco (ILO EPLex). In Austria, a social plan (Sozialplan) is a legal instrument of collective labour law (Gerlach, 2017). In France, the social plan was reformed into the “employment safeguard plan” (Plan de sauvegarde de l’emploi) which includes measures to facilitate the redeployment of dismissed workers (Blatman, 2017). In the Netherlands, further to the 2015 reform, it is possible to sign a collective labour agreement (CLA) which stipulates that instead of the public administrative body, a CLA-Commission may decide on the application of dismissals for economic reasons. The CLA must be chaired by an independent personality and the CLA can provide for applicable criteria in addition to the official ones (Boot and Erkens, 2017). In Slovenia, the Supreme Court on several occasions has affirmed that the employer has to adopt a social plan which is a formal act with obligatory content (Blaha, 2017).

Depending on the extent of the social consequences of a collective dismissal, and on the role of the trade unions (workers’ representatives), the development of a social plan may or may not be the object of consultations, and possibly involve public authorities. In some cases, a social plan can be agreed upon with a works council without presenting it up to negotiations with trade unions (workers’ representatives), or even decided upon unilaterally by the employer. The participation of the State authorities in the elaboration of a social plan often guarantees such additional measures as training programmes to workers and wage subsidies to recruiting employers.

Depending on the scale of collective dismissals, a social plan may have to be defined for a specific region, and may last for several years. Stark examples of the latter include social plans for “mono-cities” – localities that strongly depend on one employer, which are a legacy of the Soviet regime in former USSR republics.

In the majority of countries, there is no specific time period established by law during which the information has to come in. “Reasonable” time periods are often suggested by law, which in practice means periods sufficient enough to mobilize trade unions. When they exist, the time frames provided by law may refer to a different reference point. For example, in Cote d’Ivoire, information is to be provided at least 8 days before the information and consultation meeting; in Poland, it was to be provided at least 45 days prior to the date of notification of termination.15 In many countries, this is an area that has been regulated by collective agreements. Time periods for information may or may not be combined with the individual notice to be given out to the employees (for an example of practice, see Box 5).

The length of the consultation may or may not be limited in the laws of different countries. Minimum limits can help ensure that enough time for an effective consultation is provided. But placing maximum limits may also be needed, both to limit the cost associated with consultations for employers and the detrimental effects for workers, who face uncertainty and psychological pressures during these times.

In practice, several consultations are usually necessary, depending on the extent to which the agreement could be reached during the first consultation. The actual length of the consultation process may hence vary within the same country and for various dismissals, and may depend on the complexity of the situation, the number of workers involved, and the type of measures that need to be agreed upon and put in place in order to mitigate the consequences of collective dismissals. Moreover, when notification to public authorities is required by law, public authorities may request additional consultations if they feel that not all options have been explored by employers and workers’ representatives, or that the consultations have not been carried out in good faith.

Box 5. Timing of information and timing of notice: examples of practice

Within the European Union context, the European Union Court of Justice judgment in Junk v Kuhnel (Case C - 188/03) clarified the concept of ‘redundancy’ within the meaning of the Council Directive 98/59/EC and provided a definitive determination of the point in time at which the event constituting redundancy (in a collective redundancy context) occurs. The Court ruled that the consultation process required by the Directive must take place before employees are given notice of dismissal, rather than after individual notices of dismissal have been issued, but before they take effect. In practice, the judgment also meant that many employers started opting out for a payment in lieu of all (or part of) notice, so that the redundancy could take place at the end of the consultation process, not at the end of the notice period following the consultation (NERA, 2016).

In recognition of the important role of information and consultation, it is not uncommon that they are conducted even in those countries where they are not legally required. For example, in Brazil, the jurisprudence “Embraer” became emblematic in 2009. Even if from the legal point of view, the employer was not obliged to consult with the trade unions, a trade union complained to the tribunal about the lack of consultation on collective dismissals, and the tribunal positively accepted the complaint in light of the importance of the dismissal that was to be undertaken. Convention No. 158, although not ratified by Brazil, was mentioned as an international reference. Similar decisions of some regional courts have constituted important precedents, which cannot be ignored by companies considering mass redundancies. Although these decisions were being partly overturned in 2010, the Superior Labour Court of Brazil highlighted the importance of collective bargaining to avoid significant job losses, and some firms continue recurring to the consultation even if they are not legally obliged (Muller, 2017).

Special procedures triggered in case of collective dismissals: Notification to competent authorities

The laws of the majority of countries contain the requirement of notifying competent authorities of terminations that the employer contemplates for reasons of an economic, technological, structural or similar nature. This concerns 101 countries with available information (Figure 4). Competent authorities that are to be notified differ across countries, and most frequently include the Ministry of Labour or Employment, the labour inspectorate, a public employment service, an unemployment insurance or social security fund.

Figure 4. Notification to public authorities: legal requirement

Source: ILO EPLex and Muller (2011). Information as of 2010. See also Annex 1.

Notification to competent authorities may be an alternative measure to the notification of workers’ representatives (Table 2). However, in the vast majority of countries, notification to both workers’ representatives and competent authorities is required.

Table 2. Examples of countries in which informing public authorities and workers’ representatives are alternative measures

Provisions

Countries

The laws require that the employer informs only the competent public authority, but not the workers’ representatives

Afghanistan, Armenia*, Azerbaijan*, Bangladesh, Botswana, Colombia, Comoros*, Honduras, India*, Kazakhstan*, Malaysia*, Mauritius, Montenegro, Panama, Philippines, Rwanda*, Sri Lanka, Seychelles, Sudan, Thailand*, Uganda*, United States of America, Yemen

The laws require that the employer informs only the workers’ representatives, but not the competent public authority

Croatia, Ethiopia, Indonesia*, New Zealand*, Nigeria (information though not consultation) South Africa*, United Republic of Tanzania*

Source: ILO EPLex and Muller (2011). Information as of 2010. For countries marked with *, the same information is still true in 2019. For all other countries, there is no information yet available for 2019.

In contrast, only 22 countries also require that collective dismissals be authorized by public authorities (Figure 5). This is a significant change from some decades ago, when, for instance, many European countries contained such legal requirement (Cosio et al., 2017; EU, 2006). Out of those 22 countries, seven are also the ones in which no information/consultation procedure with workers’ representatives is required: Afghanistan, Colombia, Honduras, India, Panama, Sri Lanka, and Sudan.

Figure 5. Authorization by public authorities: legal requirement

Source: ILO EPLex and Muller (2011). Information as of 2010. See also Annex 1.

The economic and social rationale of notification is to improve risk-sharing and redistribute economic losses among tripartite economic actors. It can allow public authorities to jointly elaborate safeguarding measures helping employers to preserve the sometimes considerable investment represented by the costs of recruiting staff with the right experience, as well as staff’s skills and experience acquired on the job and sometimes through expensive training (GS 1995). It can also prevent the loss of firm-specific human capital. Measures such as work-sharing, reduced hours of work, and restrictions on overtime, allow to rationalize the workforce and to save upon other costs, such as costs of severance payment that need to be paid to terminated workers (ibid, p.118; European Commission, 2009). In many countries, the involvement of public authorities to the joint elaboration of measures mitigating terminations helps ensure that such measures are financed by the State. For example, reductions in the hours of work may not necessarily result in the loss of salary, if state compensation can cover the shortfall; this can be a means to preserve the production capacities of the enterprise at little, or no, additional cost. Some employers may also qualify for wage subsidies for retained or rehired workers.

The content of notifications to competent authorities differs across countries, and includes, among others, the reasons for the terminations, the number and categories of workers likely to be affected, and the period over which the terminations are intended to be carried out. The most significant differences observed are in those countries that also require notification to workers’ representatives. Typically, in case when workers’ representatives are also to be informed, the employer must indicate to the competent authority the information it has given to workers’ representatives, and also provide the information on the consultation and its outcomes, including the communication of the workers’ representatives’ response (GS 1995). In numerous EU countries, a copy of the notification to public authorities must also be sent to the workers’ representatives, who may send their comments to the competent public authority. In countries where no information/consultation procedure with workers’ representatives is required, but the employer is required to ask the competent public authority to authorize dismissals, the information to be provided also includes grounds for termination and the necessary justification for terminations (ex.: Colombia, Panama). The form of notification is usually written.

The timing of notification to competent public authorities also varies across countries. In some, it must be effectuated after information and consultation of workers’ representatives. In others, it precedes notification of workers’ representatives. Laws may also foresee various periods of time within which collective redundancies may take effect after notification; the period being used by the competent public authority to seek solutions. Sometimes, public authorities may have to be notified several times, before and after the consultation process with workers’ representatives. In some countries (most of the EU), public authorities are granted with the power to reduce or extend the period following notification, in cases where the problems cannot be resolved within the initial period (EU, 2006). In such cases, employers are informed of any extension and the grounds for it before expiry of the initial period.

From the economic viewpoint, giving the social partners sufficient time to negotiate the dismissals and elaborate social plans is to be weighed against the macroeconomic cost of not doing so, or of negotiating poorly defined social plans. Either could result in mass dismissals and resulting mass unemployment, wider social unrest and adverse political consequences.

Authorization by competent authorities is also part of the timing schedule for collective dismissals, which may sometimes run concurrently with the information and consultation process with workers’ representatives. In case no public authorization is received, the employers may still have an option of triggering a series of individual dismissals, which may take a longer time to complete, and be challenged if a collective dismissals’ procedure is perceived as not respected.

While the laws of many countries contain the legal obligation to inform a competent public authority in case of terminations for economic or similar reasons, it does not mean that the role of competent authorities is equivalent. Indeed, the exact role is determined by a number of factors, starting from which the competent authority is to be involved and what its role is: whether it is essentially a labour inspectorate or an employment administration with social security or public employment functions. The relevant competent authority may also be determined by the geographical extent of collective dismissals, whether they are single-region or multi-regional (Countouris et al., 2016).

The role of the competent authorities ranges from monitoring the dismissal process (ex.: UK), to systematically and proactively verifying the substance of dismissals and the extent to which a general interest of the economy is respected (ex.: Greece), to requesting additional consultations when necessary (ex.: the Netherlands), to assisting parties in finding solutions (ex.: Portugal), to carrying out conciliations (ex.: Peru, Tunisia). Competent authorities are often directly and proactively involved in a joint elaboration of social measures to mitigate the effects of terminations (ex.: France).

In some jurisdictions, in consultation with the local employment services and trade unions (or workers’ representatives), public administrations may suspend collective dismissals for a given period, if the labor market situation is particularly unfavorable. Such suspensions may have limits provided by statutory laws. For example, they can last up to 60 days in Cambodia, 6 months in the Russian Federation, 1 year in Belarus, or be without any statutory limit in Venezuela (Muller, 2011).

In countries where the authorization of public authorities is mandated by law, some may only have administrative powers and a purely administrative function of approving collective dismissals as long as the procedures are respected (ex.: India). Others may also to some extent exercise political discretion, which may be manifested in different ways depending on the electoral and economic cycles. Some of those public authorities may have an almost unlimited discretion over authorizations of dismissals, which often has to be exercised within a short period of time before the authorization can be considered as granted automatically (ex: Greece prior to the 2017 reform). In others, if an agreement is reached between the employer and workers, the administrative authorities must authorize collective dismissals. Finally, in some jurisdictions, several public authorities need to intervene.

The roles of public authorities before collective dismissals are co-determined with their roles after such dismissals. The extent and the nature in which public authorities are involved in the joint development of measures mitigating the effects of collective dismissals with the social partners may have additional bearing as to whether the notification and authorization would be a purely administrative gesture. A further consideration is the extent to which public authorities are involved in deploying such measures – whether retraining (a dominant component of European public policies mitigating the consequences of dismissals: Eurofound, 2011), helping to find alternative employment, providing income support or subsidies to employers for retaining workers, or combining income support with short-time working or temporary lay-off schemes. In some jurisdiction, as in France, when it comes to a large redundancy plan due to a major restructuring with major local economic impacts, the public authorities may share with the firms the financial burden of the redundancy plan, by financing vocational training, reducing taxes and social expenses. A unit in the ministry of finance in charge of such action is solicited by the early notification of the redundancy plan.

Once the authorization for terminations is granted by competent authorities, it may nevertheless be still contested or challenged in court. Depending on the jurisdiction, parties may start a litigation procedure or seek resolution from other competent public authorities. The authorization of a public authority may be refused if legal provisions with regard to termination have not been complied with (GS 1995).

Special measures to avert or minimize dismissals for economic reasons and to mitigate their effects

Figure 6 shows countries which do and which do not require, by statutory law, that the employers consider alternative measures before termination of the employment. This legal requirement exists in 70 countries with available information.

Figure 6. Legal provisions requiring the employer to seek alternatives to dismissals

Source: ILO EPLex and Muller (2011). Information as of 2010. See also Annex 1.

The most frequent measures found in national laws or experienced in national practice, among those listed in the ILS, include finding alternative employment, early retirements, and reduction of overtime. Other measures, including work-sharing and temporary part-time, are usually more of a prerogative of collective agreements. In some countries, the absence of consideration of alternative measures to avoid or reduce the number of dismissals can invalidate or nullify the dismissals (ex.: France, Germany). Even if it may not always be possible to apply such alternative measures, some countries considered that they should at least be examined. In economic downturns specifically, governments may put forward specific measures of paying the salaries of those workers who are in “technical unemployment,” or allowing for delays in paying social security contributions and taxes, in order to prevent collective dismissals.

Many of these different measures were used in response to the global economic crisis of 2008-2011, at the company, but also at the regional or state level. Some enterprises, particularly in Germany, but also in Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Estonia, the Russian Federation, and Indonesia, have prioritized internal flexibility measures over terminations, through policies of work-sharing, also called “short-time work” or “partial unemployment” (see Box 6 for examples). In Germany, work-sharing arrangements had already been part of collective agreements prior to the crisis, and both workers and employers had experience with such measures, facilitating its deployment during the crisis (ILO, 2016). There are also examples of using working time (time-saving) accounts in order to increase flexibility in production to meet the fluctuations in demand and secure employment (ILO, 2011a).

Box 6. Temporary reduction of working hours as an anti-crisis measure

Bulgaria

An anti-crisis agreement was adopted in 2010, and featured, among other measures, the introduction of flexible working hours, part-time work for a period not exceeding three months, and unpaid leave for economic reasons. This resulted in substantial growth of reduced hours and part-time work. Some of it was subsidized by the state by “equal to one-half of the minimum salary per month” (Kirov 2010, p. 47). Spill-over effects were also observed in that companies which did not qualify for state subsidies also reduced working time and put numerous employees on paid or unpaid leaves.

Czech Republic

In 2009, two large automotive companies introduced four-day work weeks for all regular employees. The lost day was compensated at 75 per cent of the usual salary.

Germany

In 2010, the social partners in the metal industry launched a time-limited ‘Future in Work’ agreement (Zukunft in Arbeit, ZiA). The agreement was destined to companies that already experimented with and exhausted work-sharing. It allowed prolonging time-sharing schemes for 6 months, and allowed further reduction of working hours provided a partial compensation was paid. Depending on the region, weekly working time could be reduced to 29 hours (Eastern Germany), or 26 to 28 hours (Western Germany). “A reduction to 28 hours is enforceable through an arbitration committee; a reduction to 26 hours is to be settled through a works agreement. Any reduction below 31 hours is to be compensated. In the case of 28 weekly working hours, 29.5 hours are to be paid, in case of 26 hours, it is a wage-equivalent of two extra hours” (Stettes 2012).

Estonia

Several medium-sized companies, such as Estiko Plastar, set a substantial proportion of employees to part-time work, without cutting wages accordingly, through installing other measures, such as abandoning the usual paid Christmas holiday, or institutionalizing work on weekends in order to meet fluctuations in demand (Masso and Krillo 2011, p. 75).

Russian Federation

Labour Code of the Russian Federation allows for an involuntary working time reduction for a period not exceeding 6 months. During the crisis, numerous enterprises thus adopted this measure, resulting in about 20 per cent of the country’s workforce reducing their hours or taking involuntary or quasi-voluntary leave (Gimpelson and Kapeliushnikov 2011, p. 11).

Indonesia

Tambunan (2011) analyses crisis-adjustment strategies adopted by SMEs in the Indonesian furniture industry through a random study of 39 SMEs. Employers were asked about the labour adjustment measures adopted since 2008. Reduction of working time was adopted by 38 per cent of firms, with all or most of the working-time related adjustments entailing cuts in wages. However, women, temporary and unskilled production workers were the first affected by these measures. As this industry in Indonesia is male-dominated, and women perform periphery unskilled tasks; in times of lower demand they are often terminated and their work is given to male skilled staff who perform those periphery tasks in addition to their main tasks.

Source: Based on Kummerling and Lehndorff, 2014; and ILO, 2016

Regarding specific criteria for selection of employees to be dismissed, 54 out of 132 countries (of which 110 have special provisions) contain specific criteria for selection of employees (Figure 7). Most frequently used criteria include skills, productivity, and social considerations. In some cases, laws may contain detailed additional criteria, such as length of service and rank class (ex.: Portugal), disability (ex.: Central African Republic) or difficult re-entry into the labour market, such as in case of elderly employees (ex.: France).

The laws may also state that specific selection criteria are to be established through collective bargaining. Indeed, the establishment of selection criteria is one of the areas that is historically subject to regulation through collective agreements and codes of good practice. Discussion of selection criteria may also be part of the consultation process.

Figure 7. Criteria for selection of workers whose employment is to be terminated for reasons of an economic, technological, structural or similar nature

Source: ILO EPLex and Muller (2011). Information as of 2010. See also Annex 1.

Recently, some countries underwent re-examination of which criteria can be used to establish priority rules for termination. In some (ex.: Romania), social considerations were removed from the list of criteria established by the law, as they could be seen as indirect discrimination. In case of redundancy processes, discrimination is most frequently claimed on sex and age grounds. In the United Kingdom, the Employment Tribunal decided in 2011 that "special treatment" for women in connection with pregnancy or childbirth must be reasonable and proportionate and found that a redundancy scoring exercise constituted sex discrimination against a man in the redundancy selection pool (Eversheds Legal Services Ltd v de Belin [2011] IRLR 448 EAT). In Slovenia, specific rules are to be respected in case of terminating, including for economic reasons, the employment relationship of a person with disabilities (Blaha, 2017). In addition, countries are progressively abandoning the last-in-first-out system, whereby the worker with lowest tenure is terminated first; this is because such principle may also be seen as indirect discrimination on the grounds of age.

The principle of priority of rehiring is retained in law in forty-three countries (Figure 8). Only about a half of them have explicit time thresholds during which giving priority to rehiring of dismissed workers is required in law. They range from 1,5 months in Romania to 3 years in the Republic of Korea, with the majority of these countries having a one-year limit (Table 3). In addition, some countries contain provisions forbidding to recreate a suppressed post within a specified time limit (ex.: Moldova; Slovakia). It is also often illegal to replace workers made redundant through a collective dismissals procedure by temporary agency workers.

Figure 8. Priority of rehiring as mandated by law

Source: ILO EPLex and Muller (2011). Information as of 2010. See also Annex 1.

Table 3. Priority of rehiring: variations in legal limits when the principle is applied

Period during which priority of rehiring applies to dismissed employees

Countries

1.5 months

Romania

6 months

China, the Netherlands, Serbia, Turkey

8 months

Cyprus

9 months

Finland, Sweden

1 year

Bangladesh, Democratic Republic of the Congo, France, Gabon, Italy, Jordan, Luxembourg, Morocco, Pakistan, Peru, Slovenia, Tunisia, Ukraine

2 years

Burkina Faso, Cambodia, Cameroon, Comoros, Niger, Senegal

3 years

Republic of Korea

No time limit

Afghanistan, Mexico, Sri Lanka, Yemen

The law makes express reference to collective agreements

Côte d’Ivoire, Madagascar

The right is embodied in the code of good practices

Lesotho, Malaysia, Tanzania

Source: Muller (2011), with adaptations. Information as of 2010.

Final assessment

This paper provided comparative data on regulations of collective dismissals worldwide, and presented the economic and social considerations which underpin these legal frameworks. Given the high level of both academic and policy debate concerning the “flexibility” or “rigidity” of EPL, such a twofold approach, combining law and economics, can hopefully contribute to the analytical work on improving the operation of the labour markets. This double reflection also provides some guidance on the need to keep in mind the fundamental objectives of EPL.

As can be seen by the discussion, there is a diversity of legal regimes and practices concerning collective dismissals. ILS are reflected in national regulations and also provide guidance for those countries that transpose their provisions into their national frameworks. The vast majority of countries recognize the market-correcting aspects of collective dismissals provisions, by providing general provisions that explicitly reflect the economic thinking. For example, having quantitative definitions allows public authorities to better prepare for the labour market and budgetary consequences, and facilitates the use of public funds for mitigating the negative consequences of collective terminations.16

These similarities across countries, however, hinder important differences in the understanding, interpretation and implementation of seemingly similar provisions. Moreover, the value of seemingly similar provisions may vary not only across countries, but also within the same country, depending on a specific dismissal plan, geographical area, sector of activity, the content of the negotiated social measures and the power of tripartite social partners in a particular point of an economic and political cycle.

There are also asymmetric implications of these provisions for workers, employers, and societies, in the sense that more worker protection implied by some regulations does not necessarily create symmetric costs to the employer. Rather, all labour market actors may find value in these provisions. The spirit of the regulations to be implemented “without prejudice to the efficient operation of the undertaking, establishment or service” (R 166, Para. 19) is often intended to help the enterprise to survive through the hardships while also helping workers to avoid terminations or mitigate their negative effects. For a social planner, the value of such measures is substantially broader, as they allow preventing unemployment and deskilling, maintain workers employability and enterprises viability.

Given this, the scope for effective comparisons of collective dismissals’ provisions across countries, without recognizing their benefits for employers and for the societies at large, may be limited. Any general cross-country assessment of EPL should strive to take into account various economic channels through which the effects of legal provisions propagate, and also the implications of alternative counterfactuals. The paper does not, however, imply, that comparative cross-country research in this area should not be undertaken. On the contrary, it highlights the benefits of interdisciplinary research as a promising path to combine and better understand the legal, social and economic implications of EPL.

Yet, going from the cross-country comparison of provisions to a meaningful assessment of whether these provisions actually do reach the goals of effectively correcting market failures is not easy. This is because some further caveats also need to be considered, and those relate, but are not limited to: (i) difficulty to establish equivalence of seemingly similar provisions across countries; (ii) availability of a wide range of dismissal options; (iii) particularly important role of collective agreements; (iv) articulation of employment termination regimes with other policies; (v) issues of coverage and enforcement of these statutory provisions. We consider these in turn:

(i) Difficulty to establish equivalence of seemingly similar provisions across countries. In a comparative cross-country perspective, caution needs to be exercised when establishing any equivalence between various legal situations or any hierarchy among them (i.e.: notification to public authorities, but not to workers’ representatives; notification, but not authorization by competent authorities). For example, the most important aspects of notifications is not the fact that they must be given, but what content they must include, as well as the nature and the relative power of public authorities. Thus, the value of notifying competent authorities is not equivalent across those countries in which it exists. But even within the same country, the exact role of a competent public authority may differ depending on the number of workers to be terminated, the overall economic climate, the services that the public authorities can provide at that time, the reasons for the dismissal (whether due to an overall economic downturn or specific circumstances of one firm), and the political situation in a country.

Furthermore, collective dismissals procedures function as a system. For example, some countries may provide for an obligation to obtain approval for collective terminations from public authorities, while others do not have such a requirement, but provide for an obligation to establish a range of social measures (a “social plan”). In some cases, such different de jure provisions would jointly result in de facto equivalent levels of protection afforded to workers, but in others they would not (see examples in Gaudu, 2011), again for the reasons of different content of procedures and different powers of tripartite actors involved into their deployment. Given this, the assessment of whether the EPL system does reach its market-correcting objective remains highly context-dependent.

(ii) Availability of a wide range of dismissal options. Many countries have comprehensive general regulations on employment termination, including varied reasons and grounds on which termination may be permitted (ILO, 2015a). Sometimes such regulations would provide – whether intentionally or not – different dismissal alternatives available to the employers (García-Martínez and Malo, 2007). Navigating between these forms of termination of employment, which may sometimes disguise one type of dismissal for another, has a bearing on the role of specific provisions and may also distort the work of some specific institutions involved in dismissals, such as labour courts (García-Martínez and Malo, 2007; Malo, 2000).

(iii) The important role of collective agreements. The issues of EPL in general and collective dismissals for economic reasons in particular are mostly regulated by law and, to a lesser extent, by ministerial decrees and codes of good practice. However, the role of social dialogue, and more specifically collective bargaining at enterprise, sectoral and national levels, is not to be neglected. Given the collective aspect of mass redundancies, collective dismissals is an area often regulated through collective agreements, and where collective bargaining traditionally plays a more important role as compared to individual dismissals (Cazes et al., 2012; Verkerke, 2009). In some countries, collective agreements complement the statutory sources of regulation. In others, whole areas of collective dismissals procedures are left entirely to collective agreements (examples include Italy or Sweden, in the area of alternative measures to dismissals: Cosio et al., 2017; see also Box 7). Collective agreements may be of a general nature and concluded before any occurrences of mass redundancies. They may also be specific, and negotiated during the process of a specific case of collective dismissals.

With a few exceptions, collective agreements often include provisions that are more generous than those provided by statutory laws. Such provisions are negotiated and agreed upon during the bargaining process, often in exchange for wage moderation, which means that they are perceived differently by both workers and employers from the provisions embedded in labour laws (Skedinger, 2010; Venn, 2009). They also concern different proportions of workers and employers across countries, depending on coverage of collective agreements, and whether collective bargaining occurred at the company, sectoral, or national level (Visser et al., 2015). The level of regulation of collective dismissals through collective bargaining often depends on the level of maturity of industrial relations in a given country (ex.: Erikson, 2017).

In addition to provisions on collective dismissals, collective agreements may cover other topics, such as practices of internal flexibility and anti-crisis related measures. Such practices, including work-sharing, part-time unemployment, part-time for old-age workers, and temporary layoffs, and can be a viable alternative to collective dismissals. They are often negotiated jointly with provisions on collective dismissals (for a review, see Glassner and Keuve, 2010). The extent to which social partners are acquainted with such alternative measures and have experience deploying them, will have a direct bearing on how often they will be used instead of collective dismissals (ILO, 2016).

Box 7. Examples of collective agreements governing collective dismissals

Some examples of national-level general agreements addressing collective dismissals include:

  • Algeria: Collective framework agreement of the private sector of 2006;

  • Belgium: Collective Labour Agreement of 1975;

  • Burkina Faso: Inter-occupational Collective Agreement of 1974;

  • Chad: General Collective Agreement of 2004;

  • Côte d’Ivoire: Inter-occupational Collective Agreement of 1977;

  • Denmark: General Agreement of 1973 (lastly amended in 1993);

  • Moldova: National tripartite agreement “Criteria of collective dismissals” of 2012;

  • Niger: Inter-occupational Collective Agreement of 1972;

  • Senegal: Inter-occupational Collective Agreement, 27 May 1982;

  • Tunisia: Framework Collective Agreement of 1973 (as amended).

In Italy, the very first regulation on collective dismissals came with the Inter-union Agreement of 1950, amended in 1965 (Curcuruto, 2017). In Denmark, all dismissals are mainly covered by two collective agreements, as the Collective Dismissals Act states that it does not apply to the extent that the employer is subject to similar obligations under a collective agreement (Klingsten, 2017). In Finland, where some laws may be complemented or even replaced by collective agreements in case an act allows for a derogation from its provisions, it is common practice to include job security provisions in collective agreements (Saloheimo, 2017). In France, the national Inter-professional Agreement of 2013 allows the job-security agreements, under which the employer temporarily commits to maintain some jobs in exchange of some changes of working conditions (Blatman, 2017). In Slovenia, many collective agreements at the branch level comprise provisions on dismissals for economic reasons (Blaha, 2017).

(iv) Articulation of employment termination regimes with other policies. Provisions for collective dismissals do not exist in a legal vacuum, and are tightly inter-related with other regulations and policies. EPL is closely linked to insurance against unemployment: if insurance markets were not suffering from imperfections and offered individually optimal unemployment insurance schemes, there would be little need for EPL (Pissarides, 2001; Bertola, 2004). Ample empirical evidence also shows that, in countries where unemployment benefit schemes and active labour market policies are less developed, worker protection is primarily achieved through EPL (ILO, 2015a; Boeri et al., 2012).

(v) Coverage and enforcement of the statutory provisions. One of the key features that virtually all studies on the role of EPL (whether individual or collective) performed on the macroeconomic level share is the assumption that EPL applies to the whole labour market (for a review, see Aleksynska and Eberlein, 2016). However, many workers and firms may be excludd from the general EPL regime. Moreover, collective dismissals’ provisions may additionally exclude some categories of workers from the scope of application or from the calculation of quantitative thresholds, starting from which collective dismissal procedures apply. Such exclusions may concern workers on fixed-term contracts, small and medium-sized enterprises, civil servants, and particular economic sectors (e.g. agriculture). Coverage of provisions also usually differs depending on the legal source of the provisions (whether this is statutory provisions or collective agreements concluded on the national, sectoral, or enterprise levels).

Coverage and the level of protection afforded by EPL, but also enforcement of these regulations and compliance with them, are complementary aspects of the EPL institution. Accounting for these aspects is important for a careful understanding and assessment of the influence of labour market regulations (Bertola et al., 2000; Ronconi, 2019).

Annex

Country

Latest year of available information

Legal change since 2010

Algeria

2019

No

Antigua and Barbuda

2018

No

Argentina

2019

No

Armenia

2018

No

Australia

2019

No

Azerbaijan

2019

No

Belgium

2019

No

Brazil

2019

No

Bulgaria

2019

No

Burkina Faso

2019

No

Cameroon

2019

No

Central African Republic

2019

No

Chile

2018

No

China

2018

No

Comoros

2019

No

Congo, Democratic Republic

2019

No

Côte d'Ivoire

2019

No

Finland

2019

No

Gabon

2019

No

Greece

2019

YES

Hungary

2019

No

India

2019

No

Indonesia

2019

No

Japan

2018

No

Jordan

2019

No

Kazakhstan

2019

No

Korea, Republic of

2019

No

Kyrgyzstan

2019

No

Lesotho

2019

No

Madagascar

2019

No

Malawi

2019

No

Malaysia

2018

No

Morocco

2019

No

Namibia

2019

No

Netherlands

2019

YES

New Zealand

2019

No

Niger

2019

No

Norway

2019

No

Portugal

2019

YES

Romania

2018

YES

Russian Federation

2019

No

Rwanda

2019

No

Senegal

2019

No

Singapore

2019

No

South Africa

2019

No

Spain

2019

YES

Switzerland

2019

No

Tanzania, United Republic of

2019

No

Thailand

2019

No

Tunisia

2019

No

Turkey

2019

No

Turkmenistan

2019

No

Uganda

2019

No

Ukraine

2019

No

United Kingdom

2019

YES

Uzbekistan

2019

No

Zimbabwe

2018

No

Source: Own compilation based on ILO EPLex database.

References

Acharya, V.; Baghai-Wadji, R.; Subramanian, K. 2013. “Labour Laws and Innovation”, in Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 56, No. 4, pp. 997–1037.

Advisory, Conciliation and Arbitration Service (ACAS). 2014. Handling large-scale redundancies, advisory booklet. Available at: https://archive.acas.org.uk/publications [Accessed 28 Apr. 2020].

Akerlof, George A. 1970. “The Market for 'Lemons': Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism” in Quarterly Journal of Economics (The MIT Press), Vol. 84, No. 3, pp. 488–500.

Aleksynska, M.; Eberlein, F. 2016. “Coverage of Employment Protection Legislation”, in
IZA Journal of Labor Policy, DOI: 10.1186/s40173-016-0073-x.

Bertola, G. 2004. “A Pure Theory of Job Security and Labour Income Risk”, in Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 71, No.1, 43–61.

2009. Labour Market Regulation: Motives, Measures, Effects, Conditions of Work and Employment Series No. 21 (Geneva, ILO).

Boeri, T.; Cazes, S. 2000. “Employment protection in industrialized countries: The case for new indicators”, in International Labor Review, Vol. 139, No. 1, pp. 57–72.

Betcherman, G. 2012. Labor Market Institutions. A Review of the Literature, Policy Research Working Paper 6276 (Washington DC, The World Bank).

2014. Labor Market Regulations: What Do We Know about Their Impacts in Developing Countries? Policy Research Working Paper 6819 (Washington DC, The World Bank).

Boeri, T.; Conde-Ruiz, I.; and Galasso, V. 2012. “The Political Economy of Flexicurity”, in Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 10, No. 4, pp. 684-715.

Jimeno, J.F. 2005. “The effects of employment protection: Learning from variable enforcement”, in European Economic Review, Vol. 49, No. 8, pp. 2057–2077.

van Ours, J. 2008. The Economics of Imperfect Labor Markets (Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press).

Blaha, M. 2017. “Collective Dismissals in Slovenia”, in Cosio et al. (eds), 2017.

Blatman, M. 2017. “Collective Dismissal in France”, in Cosio et al. (eds), 2017.

Boot, G.; Erkens, Y. 2017. “Collective dismissal in the Netherlands”, in Cosio et al. (eds), 2017.

Booth.; A.L.; Zoega, G. 2003. “On the Welfare Implications of Firing Costs”, in European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 19, No. 4, pp. 759-75.

Buechtemann C.F. 1992. “Employment Security & Labour Markets: Assumptions, International Evidence and Theoretical Implications”, in C.F. Buechtemann (ed.), Employment Security and Labor Market Behavior: Interdisciplinary Approaches and International Evidence, (Ithaca, NY, ILR Press, Cornell).

Cahuc, P.; Zylberberg, A. 2006. The Natural Survival of Work: Job Creation and Job Destruction in a Growing Economy (Cambridge, MA, MIT Press).

Cazes, S.; Khatiwada, S.; Malo, M. 2012. Employment Protection and Collective Bargaining: Beyond the Deregulation Agenda, Employment Working Paper No. 133 (Geneva, ILO).

Coase, R. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm”, in Economica (Blackwell Publishing), Vol. 4, No. 6, pp. 386–405.

1960. “The Problem of Social Cost”, in Journal of Law and Economics (University of Chicago Press), Vol. 3, pp. 1–44.

Collins, H.; Ewing, K.; McColgan, A. 2012. Labour Law (Cambridge University Press).

Countouris, N.; Deakin, S.; Freedland, M.; Koukiadaki, A.; Prassl, J. 2016. Report on collective dismissals: A comparative and contextual analysis of the law on collective redundancies in 13 European countries (Geneva, ILO).

Cosio, R.; Curcuruto, F.; Di Cerbo, V.; Mammone, G. (eds). 2017. Collective Dismissals in the European Union (Kluwer Law International BV).

Cremers, J.; Bekker, S.; Dekker, R. 2017. “The Dutch polder model: Resilience in times of crisis”, in I. Guardiancich and O. Molina (eds): Talking through the crisis: Social dialogue and industrial relations trends in selected EU countries (Geneva, ILO).

Curcuruto, F. 2017. “Collective diamissals in Italy”, in Cosio et al. (eds), 2017.

Deakin, S. 2014. Labour Law and Inclusive Development, CBR Working Paper No. 458 (University of Cambridge).

Deakin, S.; Fenwick, C.; Sarkar, P. 2014. “Labour Law and Inclusive Development: The Economic Effects of Industrial Relations Laws in Middle-Income Countries”, in M. Schmiegelow and H. Schmiegelow (eds): Institutional Competition between Common Law and Civil Law (Springer), pp. 185-209.

ETUI, 2016a. Reforms Watch. Labour Law Reforms in Spain – Background Summary, Available at: https://www.etui.org/ReformsWatch/Spain/Labour-market-reforms-in-Spain-background-summary [Accessed February 2018].

2016b. Reforms Watch. Labour Law Reforms in Portugal – Background Summary. Available at: https://www.etui.org/ReformsWatch/Portugal/Labour-law-reforms-in-Portugal-background-summary [Accessed February 2018].

2016c. Reforms Watch. Labour Law Reforms in the Netherlands – Background Summary. Available at: https://www.etui.org/ReformsWatch/Netherlands/The-state-of-labour-market-reforms-background-summary [Accessed February 2018].

Erikson, M. 2017. “Collective dismissal in Estonia”, in Cosio et al. (eds), 2017.

Eurofound, 2011. Public Instruments to Support Restructuring in Europe, ERM Report 2011 (Luxembourg).

European Union, 2006. Termination of employment relationships. Legal situation in the member States of the European Union (Brussels, EU Directorate General Employment, Social Affairs and Equal Opportunities).

García-Martínez, P.; Malo, M. 2007. “The strategic use of dismissal legislation: an empirical analysis using Spanish data”, in European Journal of Law and Economics,Vol. 23, pp. 151–167.

Gaudu, F. 2011. “Collective Redundancies for Economic Motives: Convergences and Controversies”, in European Labour Law Journal, Vol. 2, No. 1, pp. 5–26.

Gerlach, R. 2017. “Collective dismissal in Austria”, in Cosio et al. (eds), 2017.

Gimpelson, V.; Kapeliushnikov, R. 2011. Labour market adjustment: is Russia different?, IZA Discussion paper No. 5588 (Bonn, Institute for the Study of Labor).

Glassner, V.; Keune, M. 2010. Negotiating the crisis? Collective bargaining in Europe during the economic downturn, Dialogue Working Paper No. 10 (Geneva, ILO).

Heinsius, J. 2009. “The European Directive on Collective Dismissals and its Implementation Deficits”, in International Journal of Comparative Labour Law and Industrial Relations, Vol. 25, No. 3, pp. 261-282.

International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2016. World Economic Outlook (Washington, DC).

International Labour Office (ILO). 1982. Termination of Employment Convention, 1982 (No. 158).

1982. Termination of Employment Recommendation, 1982 (No. 166).

2009a. Note on C158 and R166 Concerning termination of Employment (Geneva, ILO).

2009b. EPLEX: Objectives and Scope of the Database. Available at: http://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/@ed_dialogue/@dialogue/documents/genericdocument/wcms_172216.pdf (Geneva).

2011a. Working time in the twenty-first century, Report for discussion at the Tripartite Meeting of Experts on Working Time Arrangements (October 2011, Geneva).

2011b. Tripartite Meeting of Experts to Examine the Termination of Employment Convention and Recommendation. Available at: http://www.ilo.org/global/standards/WCMS_146547/lang--en/index.htm

2013. National Tripartite Social Dialogue: An ILO guide for improved governance (Geneva).

2015a. Employment protection legislation: Summary indicators in the area of terminating regular contracts (individual dismissals) (Geneva).

2015b. Compendium of International Labour Conventions and Recommendations (Geneva).

2016. Non-standard Forms of Employment: Understanding Challenges, Shaping Prospects (Geneva).

2019. EPLex Database on Employment Protection Legislation. Available at: www.ilo.org/dyn/eplex/termmain.home (Geneva).

ILO Committee of Experts on the Application of Conventions and Recommendations (CEACR). 1993. Workers with family responsibilities – General Survey of the Reports on the Workers with Family Responsibilities Convention (No. 156) and Recommendation (No. 165), 1981. Report III (Part 4B), International Labour Conference (ILC), 80th Session, 1993.

1995. Protection against unjustified dismissal – General Survey on the Termination of Employment Convention (No. 158) and Recommendation (No. 166), 1982, Report III (Part 4B), ILC, 82th Session, 1995.

2012. Giving Globalization a human face – General Survey on the Fundamental Conventions Concerning Rights at Work in Light of the ILO Declaration on Social Justice for a Fair Globalization, 2008, Report III (Part 1B), ILC, 101st Session, 2012.

Kaufman, B. 2007. “The impossibility of a perfectly competitive labour market”, in Cambridge Journal of Economics, Vol. 31, pp. 775-87.

Kirov, V. 2010. Anticipating and managing restructuring – Bulgaria, National Seminar background paper (Brussels, European Commission/ITC ILO).

Klingsten, M. 2017. “Collective Dismissal in Denmark”, in Cosio et al. (eds), 2017.

Kummerling, A.; Lehndorff, S. 2014. The Use of Working time-related crisis response measures during the Great Recession, Conditions of Work and Employment Series No. 44 (Geneva, ILO).

Lee, S.; McCann, D. 2011. “New Directions in Labour Regulation Research”, in S. Lee and D, McCann (eds): Regulating for Decent Work (Palgrave MacMillan).

Malo, M.A. 2000. A simple model of severance pay determination: The case of individual dismissals in Spain. Labour, 14(2), 269–290.

Pérez, J. 2003. “Individual dismissals in Europe and the United States: A model on the influence of the legal framework on firing costs”, in European Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 15, No. 1, pp. 47-63.

Masso, J.; Krillo, K. 2011. “Mixed adjustment forms and inequality effects in Estonia” in V. Whitehead (ed): Work inequalities in the crisis – Evidence from Europe (Cheltenham, Elgar), pp. 38-102.

Messenger, J.; Ghosheh, N. 2013. Work Sharing during the Great Recession: New developments and beyond (Geneva, ILO).

Muller, A. 2011. Employment Protection Legislation Tested by the Economic Crisis, DIALOGUE in Brief No. 3 (Geneva, ILO).

2012. Labour Law reforms at the Crossroads of ILO Standards and OECD and World Bank Indexes: A Global Review of Regulation on Collective Redundancies, paper prepared for the 16th ILERA World Congress, Philadelphia.

2017. “Regulation of Collective Redundancies: European Union Countries at the Mirror of Global Standards and Trends”, in Cosio et al. (eds), 2017.

National Employment Rights Authority (NERA). 2016. Collective Redundancies Factsheet (Cardow, Ireland). Available at: https://www.workplacerelations.ie/en/publications_forms/collective_redundancies_factsheet.pdf [Accessed April 2020].

Nickell, S.; Layard, R. 1999. “Labor Market Institutions and Economic Performance”, in O. Ashenfelter and D. Card (eds), Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3 (Amsterdam), pp. 3029–3084.

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), 2007. Going for Growth (Paris).

2009. OECD Employment Outlook 2009 (Paris).

2013. OECD Employment Outlook 2013 (Paris).

Oyer, P.; Schaefer, S. 2000. “Layoffs and litigation”, in Rand Journal of Economics, Vol. 31, No. 2, 345–358.

2002. “Litigation Costs and Returns to Experience”, in American Economic Review (American Economic Association), Vol. 92, No. 3, pp. 683–705.

Pissarides, C. 2001. “Employment Protection”, in Labour Economics, Vol. 8. pp. 131–159.

Ronconi, L. 2019. Enforcement of Labor Regulations in Developing Countries, IZA World of Labor 2019: 457 doi: 10.15185/izawol.457

Saloheimo, J. 2017. “Collective Dismissal in Finland”, in Cosio et al. (eds), 2017.

Skedinger, P. (ed.) 2010. Employment Protection Legislation: Evolution, Effects, Winners and Losers (Northampton, MA, Edward Elgar Publishing).

Stettes, O. 2012. Germany: Evolution of wages during the crisis. Trends and relations with other working conditions. Available at: http://www.eurofound.europa.eu/observatories/eurwork/comparative-information/national-contributions/germany/germany-evolution-of-wages-during-the-crisis [Accessed June 2017].

Solow, R. 1992. The Labour Market as a Social Institution (Cambridge, Blackwell).

Trimikliniotis, N. 2017. “Collective Dismissal in Cyprus”, in Cosio et al. (eds), 2017.

Uluitu, A.G. 2017. “Collective dismissal in Romania”, in Cosio et al. (eds), 2017.

Valverde, A.M. 2017. “Collective dismissals in Spain”, in Cosio et al. (eds), 2017.

Venn, D. 2009. Legislation, collective bargaining and enforcement: Updating the OECD employment protection indicators, Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers No. 17 (Paris, OECD).

Verkerke, R. 2009. “Discharge”, in K.G. Dau-Schmidt, S.D. Harris and O. Lobel (eds): Labor and Employment Law and Economics (Edward Elgar).

Vilarinho Marques, F.C.; Mendes Ferreira Roberto, P. 2017. “Collective dismissal in Portugal”, in Cosio et al. (eds), 2017.

Visser, J.; Hayter, S.; Gammarano, R. 2015. Trends in Collective Bargaining Coverage: Stability, Erosion or Decline?, Labour Relations and Collective Bargaining Issue Brief No. 1 (Geneva, ILO).

World Bank. 2013. The World Development Report 2013: Jobs (Washington, DC).

Acknowledgements

The authors are particularly grateful to Philippe Marcadent and Janine Berg (ILO INWORK) for their support in the production of this paper, as well as to colleagues of the Bureau for Employers’ Activities and of the Bureau of Workers’ Activities, and to other ILO colleagues - Colin Fenwick, Valérie Van Goethem, Anna Torriente, Franco Amato, Cristina Campayo, and Tzehainesh Teklè - for valuable guidance and comments. The paper also benefitted from a methodological discussion with the following external experts: Kadriye Bakirci (Hacettepe University Faculty of Law, Ankara Turkey), Nicola Countouris (University College London, London UK), Bertrand Du Marais (Conseiller d'État; FIDES and University Paris Nanterre, Paris France), Miguel A. Malo (University of Salamanca, Salamanca Spain), Astrid Sanders (London School of Economics and Political Science, London UK), whose active involvement and comments on earlier stages of the paper are gratefully acknowledged. All remaining errors are ours.

1

In this paper, the term “collective dismissals for economic reasons” is understood similarly to the expression “collective redundancies” used in many countries. The term “lay-offs” is not used in this paper as in some countries it means temporary suspension of the employment relationship.

2

Some authors distinguish three EPL pillars: protection in case of individual dismissals, protection (special procedures) in case of collective dismissals, and regulation of fixed-term contracts. For an overview, see, for example, Cazes et al. (2012).

3

Also explicitly recognized by the ILO Committee of Experts on the Application of Conventions and Recommendations (CEACR) in the General Survey on Protection against unjustified dismissal (ILO CEACR, 1995), hereinafter “GS 1995”.

4

In some legislations, such pursued objectives are explicitly expressed. The right to job security is guaranteed, for example, by the Portuguese Constitution (Vilarinho Marques & Mendes Ferreira Roberto, 2017). The main aim of the Danish Collective Dismissal Act is to protect the employees (Klingsten, 2017).

6

The ILO has carried out several reviews of the ILS to examine their continued relevance. C158 and R166 have been reviewed by the Cartier Working Party which carried out its work between 1995 and 2002 with a view to make a recommendation on the status of ILS and identify those to be promoted by the ILO.

C158 and R166 were the only instruments for which no conclusions were reached. The status of C158 and R166 will be reviewed again by the SRM tripartite working group which was established in 2015.

7

ILO conventions are divided into fundamental conventions whose respect by member States is required regardless of whether they are ratified or not, governance conventions, and technical conventions. C158 belongs to the latter ones. The state of ratification of all conventions is available at ILO NORMLEX database.

8

See ILO CEACR, 1993, para. 266. See also ILO CEACR, 2012, para 782-786.

9

ILO, 2019. The ILO EPLex database monitors regulations of contracts of employment and termination of employment. It contains rich and unique comparative information on laws and main national collective agreements governing employment protection in 95 countries, and over the period 2009-2019 (the time coverage varies depending on a country). The database does not reflect case law, and neither collective agreements other than those concluded on the national level (ILO, 2009b).

10

Note that staggering or scattering redundancies, within the legal limits, can precisely be meant by the employer to avoid massive negative effects of collective dismissals happening all at the same time.

11

This practice is observed, notably, in the UK (for details, see ACAS, 2014).

12

See ILO EPLex database for the full details of the law. The information is available as of 2010; and is unchanged at the date of the publications of this paper.

13

At the same time, where quantitative definitions are absent, special procedures in case of termination for economic and other similar reasons may be triggered starting from one, or a relatively small, number of workers, thus lifting protections for all.

14

In the USA, there is no general statutory obligation to have prior consultations with trade unions (workers' representatives). However, for an employer whose employees are represented by a union, a change made to terms and conditions of employment that are mandatory subjects of bargaining (which may include a plant closure or mass lay off) carry an obligation to bargain with the union under Section 8(a)(5) of the National Labor Relations Act of 1935 , 29 USC § 158(a)(5), if the change is "material and substantial" (see Fresno Bee, 339 NLRB 1214 (1993); NLRB v. Katz, 369 U.S. 736, 743 (1962)). Assuming that the decision to relocate work or close a plant with the result of collective dismissals represent a "material and substantial" change, an employer must bargain with the bargaining representative of the employees over the effects. So called 'effects bargaining' must occur before the decision is implemented.  The bargaining obligation requires only that the employer negotiate in good faith with the union until an agreement is reached or the parties arrive at impasse. If the parties arrive at a good faith impasse, the employer is entitled to implement its final proposal at that time (29 U.S.C.A. § 158(a)(5)). For more information, see ILO EPLex.

15

Example referring to provision in place in the mid-1990s (Source: GS 1995).

16

One caveat, however, is that public authorities should also know the exact distribution of enterprises by their size in each economy, as well as the distribution of employment across enterprises. Such distribution, however, may be endogenous to the quantitative definition of collective dismissals (Boeri and Jimeno, 2005), because some firms may deliberately maintain the size of their workforce below certain threshold in order to avoid applications of these laws. In a comparative cross-countries perspective, this also means that a different percentage of a workforce in a given country will be protected by seemingly similar rules.